CHAPTER FIVE - OTHER ISSUES
5.1
While a large amount of the evidence received by the
Committee fell within the three broad themes of taxation on families, taxation
on low income earners, and compliance, evidence on other issues was also
received. This chapter will consider evidence in relation to:
-
vertical fiscal imbalance;
Vertical Fiscal Imbalance
5.2
Vertical Fiscal
Imbalance (VFI) refers to the situation where there is a systemic imbalance
between the revenue-raising capacity and the expenditure responsibilities of
different levels of government. In Australia,
the Commonwealth government raises significantly more money than it spends, and
the State and Territory governments spend significantly more than they raise. As
a result, there must be a system enabling Commonwealth revenue to be
transferred to the States and Territories to meet their spending needs.
Origins of VFI
5.3
From Federation until 1942, State governments imposed
income tax and company tax. From about the time of the First World War, the
Commonwealth also imposed taxes in these areas. Taxes from the two levels of
government were collected concurrently. During the Second World War, to fund
the war effort, the Commonwealth Government determined that income and company
taxes must rise. Introducing the Income Tax (War-Time Arrangements) Bill
1942, then Treasurer, the Hon. Joseph Chifley MP stated:
The Government believes that in this emergency it must have
available to it the maximum taxable capacity of the nation. The whole of the
taxable field is not available to the Commonwealth while State taxes are levied
upon incomes at various levels. If a single income tax be imposed to raise
revenue for the requirements of both Commonwealth and States, it will be
possible to levy that tax on every section of the taxable field, and apply it
to the nation as a whole on the basis of equality of sacrifice and equality of
citizenship. []
Every honourable member who has occupied the position of
Treasurer can testify that the differing rates of Commonwealth and State
taxation form a maddening maze of figures which must be studied whenever the
preparation of a budget calls for additional Commonwealth revenue. The position
has become so serious that strong and definite action must be taken by the
Commonwealth to cut this gordian knot, if any simplification of Commonwealth
and State taxes is to be achieved in the interests of the war effort.[158]
5.4
The Commonwealth accomplished its purpose by raising
income taxes to a high level, and by introducing (in the State Grants (Income Tax Reimbursement) Act 1942) a scheme whereby
States which did not impose an income tax would be reimbursed for their lost
revenue from the Commonwealth-collected income tax. The Commonwealth could not
forbid the states from also collecting income taxes. However, the effect of the
State Grants Act meant that no state would be better off by collecting an
income tax.
5.5
In addition, as a war measure, the Commonwealth assumed
control of all state apparatus (including staff and premises) for collecting
income tax.
5.6
South Australia,
Victoria, Queensland
and Western Australia went to the
High Court to test the constitutionality of the uniform tax scheme. The High
Court found that the scheme was valid.[159]
5.7
More than a decade after the war ended, Victoria
and New South Wales returned to
the High Court, seeking a reconsideration of the uniform tax scheme, arguing
that the scheme had been a war-time scheme which should have ended following
the war. The High Court found that the scheme remained valid, and that 'the
whole plan of uniform taxation has become very much a recognised part of the
Australian fiscal system.'[160] This
remains the case today.
Previous attempts to address VFI
5.8
While uniform taxation may have become a recognised
part of the Australian fiscal system, State (and Territory) discontent with VFI
has also become a customary feature of it. The process by which the
Commonwealth transfers revenue to the states has always been and remains a
source of discord. A number of attempts have been made to deal with the ongoing
difficulties created by VFI.
Early attempts
5.9
The Commonwealth Grants Commission was established in
1933 to assess claims for tied grants under s.96 of the Constitution. On the
commencement of uniform taxation, it was also given responsibility for
assessing and advising government on the appropriate distribution of the
proceeds from the uniform taxation scheme. It retains that role today, though
the rules which guide its assessments have changed several times over that
period.[161]
5.10
The initial formula was introduced in 1946, and
determined that 'the base amounts in that year for each State shall be
increased each your through a series of factors based on a State's total
population, its density, schoolchildren and average wages.'[162]
5.11
That formula remained in place until 1959, when Prime
Minister Menzies convened a Premiers
Conference to consider options for a new funding formula. Victoria,
in particular, felt it was at a disadvantage under the 1946 formula. The
following exchange, from the Sydney
Morning Herald, suggests the flavour of debates on this issue:
Mr
Menzies [Prime Minister]: So far as you are
concerned the tax reimbursements ought to be on a per capita basis?
Mr
Bolte [Premier of Victoria]: Well, far
nearer than it is now.
Mr
Cahill [Premier of NSW]: You would disregard
area in favour of population?
Mr
Bolte: Not Entirely.
The South
Australian Premier, Sir Thomas
Playford, said that while population was an
important factor so also was the size of the school population. Victoria
had, proportionally, the lowest school population in the Commonwealth. This
should be taken into consideration in the formula.[163]
5.12
The first Premiers Conference, in March 1959, failed to
resolve the formula issue. Agreement was reached at a second conference in June.
The Commonwealth agreed to change the nature of the grants from being 'tax
reimbursement grants' and 'supplementary grants' (for smaller states) to a
system of 'financial assistance grants' which would be increased as follows:
The financial assistance grants to each State after 1959-60 were
to be increased in accordance with (a) annual increases in the State's
population, (b) annual increases in the level of average wages of Australia as
a whole, and (c) a betterment factor of 10 per cent to be applied to the
increases in average wages (so that an increase of 3 per cent in average wages
would be increased to 3.3 per cent).[164]
5.13
After a Premiers Conference in 1965, the 'betterment
factor' became more generous, increasing to 1.2 per cent and applying to the
grant increases as a whole, not just the increases due to wage growth. In 1970,
Commonwealth grants to the states increased still further: the betterment
factor rose to 1.8 per cent, and the Commonwealth agreed to fund additional
capital works, and to fund $1 billion for state debt reduction.
New Federalism
5.14
By the mid 1970s, the States again argued that revenue
from the Commonwealth was inadequate. In the 1975 federal election campaign, Prime
Minister Fraser campaigned on a policy known
as "New Federalism". The key element of New Federalism was a proposal
to give each State a specified share of income tax receipts (as opposed to
giving them a grant funded from those receipts), then eventually to allow the
States to impose an income tax surcharge in their state (effectively a state
income tax to be collected above and beyond the Commonwealth income tax). This
system was unsuccessful, primarily because the Commonwealth did not lower its
own income tax rate to make room for the state surcharges:
Much of the blame for the failure of the Fraser Government's
attempts at fiscal reform must, however, rest with its faulty design of the tax
sharing system. While this guaranteed the States a fixed share of personal
income tax collections it simultaneously, by failing to reduce Commonwealth tax
rates and therefore the level of shared tax revenues, permitted the States to
avoid any necessity to impose income tax surcharges to make good the reductions
in general revenue assistance which that action would have entailed. For their
part, if the States had been sincere in their protestations about the need for
a restoration of their taxing power, they would have insisted on the
Commonwealth making tax room. But they found it politically more attractive to
allow the Commonwealth to continue to impose taxation on their behalf and to
reserve for themselves the right to argue about shares.[165]
The Intergovernmental Agreement on
the Reform of Commonwealth-State Financial Relations
5.15
In 1999, as part of the development of the New Tax
Package, the Commonwealth, States and Territories concluded an agreement known
as the Intergovernmental Agreement on the Reform of Commonwealth-State
Financial Relations ('the IGA'). The IGA is still in force.
5.16
The key features of the IGA are:
-
provision of all revenue from the Goods and
Services Tax (GST) to the States and Territories;
-
cessation of Financial Assistance Grants;
-
removal of a range of State and Territory taxes,
including debit taxes and some stamp duties; and
-
a promise by the Commonwealth to maintain the
level of Specific Purpose Payments (SPPs, tied grants made under s.96 of the
Constitution) to the States and Territories.
5.17
Clause 8 of the IGA reads:
8.
The Commonwealth will distribute GST revenue grants
among the States and Territories in accordance with horizontal fiscal equalisation
(HFE) principles subject to the transitional arrangements set out below and
other relevant provisions of this agreement.[166]
5.18
Horizontal fiscal equalisation was described by Garnaut
and FitzGerald as:
Arrangements within a federation to reduce or eliminate
difference in the fiscal ability of States to carry out the functions for which
they are responsible.[167]
5.19
While the IGA refers to 'horizontal fiscal equalisation
principles' it does not actually define those principles. This has been a
driver for continued discord among the States and Territories. The New South
Wales Government submission to this inquiry, for instance, stated:
New South Wales
has long argued for reform of Australias
system of horizontal fiscal equalisation. Currently the subsidy from New
South Wales to recipient States is about $1.2
billion, compared with an equal per capita distribution of GST revenue grants. This
is equivalent to 11 percent of own-source State tax revenue. The NSW Government
believes that the subsidies resulting from the current system are too large,
are not well justified, and place too high a burden on the donor States. This
burden is not expected to ease, with projections made by the South Australian
Treasury, on behalf of all States, indicating that the subsidy from donor to
recipient States will increase by over 80 percent over the next ten years.[168]
VFI and this inquiry
5.20
New South Wales,
Queensland, South
Australia, Tasmania
and Victoria all made submissions
to this inquiry dealing with VFI. The Premier of Victoria, in his submission,
outlined a number of concerns which he said are shared by all States and
Territories:
-
the impact
on public policy development. There is an incentive for States to develop
public policy with regard to potential grant share implications, to the
detriment of efficient and productive outcomes;
-
the
unsustainable and inconsistent level of detail required by the current
equalisation system. The current equalisation process requires
extraordinary amounts of data. The resources involved in collecting this data
are a significant cost to all States, and often detract from efficient and
effective delivery of services;
-
the lack
of transparency within the current system. The level of detail of the
current system and the complexity of its methodology reduce transparency; and
-
the
inefficiencies created by specific purpose payments. Specific purpose
payments impose considerable administrative costs on both the Commonwealth and
the States. They also blur accountability between levels of government and
reduce the flexibility of States in providing services.[169]
5.21
The final issue raised by the Premier of Victoria, the
current administration of Special Purpose Payments (SPPs), was also a concern
for a number of other States. The Treasurer of Tasmania stated:
a consistent theme of recent SPP negotiations is the
positioning of the Commonwealth to withdraw funding as GST revenues to the
states increase. This has taken the form of tightening the amount of SPP funds
available either through overt reductions in funding over time, or through
inadequate indexation of the funding base. The systematic reduction of SPP
funding across the board calls into question whether the states will in fact be
better off financially, notwithstanding the receipt of Commonwealth transfers
tied to the expected growth over time in GST revenues.[170]
5.22
The Premier of South Australia made similar comments:
The Commonwealth should commit to ensuring that SPPs are
maintained in real terms from year to year. However the commitment needs to go
further than that. If the Commonwealth maintains SPPs in real terms but
increases the matching requirements associated with these SPPs it is
effectively appropriating State revenues for Commonwealth policy purposes. Another
danger is that the Commonwealth can effectively shift responsibilities to the
States. There are a number of examples where the Commonwealth has encouraged
States to set up jointly funded programs but then ceased their funding after 2
or 3 years. The State is then faced with making up the shortfall or cutting
back or cancelling the program.[171]
5.23
The Queensland Government stated:
Although the Commonwealth undertakes in the IGA not to reduce
SPPs as part of the new tax arrangements, there are from time to time
statements made by Commonwealth Ministers that States should use GST revenue to
fund areas of expenditure currently funded by the Commonwealth through SPPs to
the State. GST revenues will genuinely benefit States if the additional
revenues are available for States to improve service delivery to their
communities. This will not be possible if the additional revenue is diverted to
fund additional expenditure responsibilities transferred from the Commonwealth
to the States.[172]
Local Government Issues
5.24
Considerations of VFI usually focus on the
Commonwealth, the States and Territories. Local Governments are in an unusual
position, as their authority, their responsibilities, and their powers to
impose taxes and charges, are all delegated by the States and the Northern
Territory.[173] However, in
recognition of the role played by local government in Australian communities,
the Commonwealth provides Financial Assistance Grants to the States and
Territories, in order that the States and Territories can pass them on to local
governments. These grants totalled more than $1.5 billion in the 2004 budget.[174]
5.25
The Australian Local Government Association, in its
submission to this inquiry, argued that the current arrangements are
unsatisfactory. Its submission stated:
There is an urgent need to reform the current tax sharing
arrangements between the Commonwealth and local government. The next stage of
intergovernmental financial reform must address the relationship between the
Commonwealth and local government as a matter of urgency.
A stable, robust tax sharing arrangement linked to a growth tax
would enable local government to strengthen itself as an institution, and
improve service delivery to communities.
Any new funding methodology must be based around the notion of
an entitlement to tax sharing rather than Commonwealth grant provision.[175]
5.26
The Municipal Association of Victoria also sought
direct funding from the Commonwealth, but is content with the current
administrative arrangements, whereby the funding is in the form of Financial
Assistance Grants:
Local government must have access to a tax transfer from the
Commonwealth in order to provide adequate services and develop local and
regional resources. This tax transfer must take the form of a general purpose
payment in recognition of local government's general competence. The current process for enabling this tax
transfer, the [Financial Assistance Grants] system, provides an appropriate
method of facilitating a tax transfer from the Commonwealth to local government
that is sensitive to the state variations in local government roles,
responsibilities and asset profiles.[176]
Tax on alcohol
5.27
Taxes have a long history of being used to increase the
cost of certain activities which public policy regards as undesirable, or undesirable
in excess. This has led, for instance, to relatively high taxes on cigarettes
and tobacco products, alcoholic beverages, and gambling. The economic rationale
for these taxes is that the taxed activities (drinking, smoking and gambling)
create negative externalities, and that it is appropriate to obtain additional
revenue to compensate for these externalities.
5.28
In this inquiry, submissions focussed on the tax
treatment of alcohol. The Alcohol and other Drugs Council of Australia outlined
the social and economic costs of excessive alcohol consumption in their
submission, which included the following observations:
-
alcohol misuse cost the Australian community
over $7.5 billion in 1998-9. This estimate included costs to the health
care system, lost production in the workplace, road accidents, premature death
and some aspects of alcohol attributable crime. It did not include the many
costs associated with pain, suffering and alcohol-related depression and
anxiety;
-
It is estimated that in 1997 alone the misuse of
alcohol resulted in 63,164 person-years of life lost (before 70 years), a total
of approximately 3290 premature deaths and over 400,000 hospital bed days;
-
The National Drug Strategy Household Survey
found in 2001 that 31% of Australians 14 years and over reported being victims
of alcohol-related anti-social behaviour in the 12 months preceding the survey.
This is twice as many who reported being victims of anti-social behaviour
related to all other drugs;
-
A Victorian report in 1988 found that alcohol
was definitely or possibly involved in 53% of several thousand reported
incidences of family violence; and
-
It is estimated that between 1990 and 1997, 31%
of all driver and pedestrian deaths on Australian roads were alcohol related.[177]
5.29
The Winemakers Federation of Australia, on the other
hand, pointed out the contribution made by the wine industry to the national
economy, including exports in excess of $2.1 billion annually, employment of
more than 30,000 people, and nearly $1 billion spent by winery visitors
engaging in wine tourism.[178]
5.30
The current system for taxation of alcohol is quite
complex, but in general, beverages other than wine are taxed on the basis of
their alcohol strength, while wines are taxed on their volume. Additionally,
alcoholic beverages attract GST.
Wine equalisation tax
5.31
Wine Equalisation Tax (WET) is a 29 percent value added
tax introduced as part of the New Tax Package, to offset the withdrawal of
wholesale sales tax. As it is a value added tax, the amount of WET depends on
the value of the wine, not its alcohol content. Consequently, premium wines
attract a larger amount of WET and cheaper wines (such as cask wines) attract a
lesser amount of WET.
5.32
While the Winemakers Federation of Australia did not
express concern regarding the operation and level of the WET[179] the Alcohol
and other Drugs Council of Australia expressed concern that the relatively low
tax on cask wine contributes to alcohol abuse:
As highlighted earlier, Australian studies have clearly shown
that consumption of cask wine (and standard beer) is more closely associated
with higher levels of violence, injury and illness than other alcoholic
beverages.
Excessive cask wine consumption is a major problem in some
Aboriginal communities. In the Alice Springs region, a
population of less than 35,000 people consumed over 1.2 million litres of cask
wine in 1998. That was equivalent to over 5,500 four-litre casks a week. Since
most of the population did not drink cask wine, these data indicate harmful
consumption by drinkers of cask wine.
The current system allows a male drinker to consume a daily
intake that is considered, by the National Health and Medical Research Council,
to be high risk for long-term harm for only $2.94 (7 or more standard drinks)
and a female drinker to do so for just $1.60 (5 or more standard drinks) if drinking
from a 4 litre wine cask.
The current situation also disadvantages small Australian
premium wine producers, many of whom concentrate on the innovative and higher
quality end of the market, in their ability to compete in the overall wine
market. The WET may actually be discouraging innovation and production of
premium wines and encouraging mass production of lower quality wines. This in
turn encourages over-consumption of cask wine, which currently represents a
high proportion of all wine sold.
The introduction of the WET has served no real policy purpose
other than to protect the interest of cask wine producers (mostly large
multinational companies) at the expense of Australias
premium wine producers. It is also at the expense of the health and well being
of many disadvantaged communities where the price of cask wine is a primary
factor influencing the amount of alcohol consumed. [180]
5.33
The 2004 budget introduced a measure to rebate the
first $290,000 of WET for each producer in Australia
(that is, the WET on the first $1 million of sales).[181] This may
offset some of the advantage the previous WET arrangements gave to cask wine,
because most of the WET rebate will be captured by small regional producers,
who often produce low-volume premium wines rather than high-volume, low-quality
cask wines. However, these budget measures do not increase the price of cask
wine, so their impact on consumption of cask wine remains uncertain.
Tax on ready-to-drink mixed spirits
5.34
Currently, low alcohol beer and mid-strength beer are
taxed at a concessional rate. According to Australian Associated Brewers, this
(combined with improvements in the taste of low alcohol beers) has resulted in
an increase in low alcohol beers to the point where 'now a quarter of all beers
sold are lower alcohol.'[182]
5.35
The Alcohol and other Drugs Council of Australia
proposed a similar scheme for ready-to-drink (RTD) mixed spirits, which have
become popular among younger drinkers. In its submission, the Council stated:
From a public health
perspective, low and mid strength products can play a significant role in the
reduction of alcohol-related harm. However, low alcohol products have had very
little market penetration among young drinkers and currently there is no
financial incentive for alcohol manufacturers to promote and produce mid and
low strength RTDs, which currently represent only 1% of the RTD market [] The
excise rate applying to low and mid-strength beer should also apply to
[ready-to-drink mixed spirits] and apple ciders with the same alcohol content [183]
5.36
In
its October 2002 report on the provisions of the Excise Tariff Amendment Bill
(No. 1) 2002 and the provisions of the Customs Tariff Amendment Bill (No. 2)
2002, the Senate Economics Legislation Committee observed:
The Committee also notes the importance of the excise system as
a tool to influence drinking habits through price mechanisms. It accepts that
excise on alcohol has a place in discouraging the consumption of high alcohol
beverages by making low alcohol products more attractive through lower prices
to the consumer. A similar excise regime to that of beer would be an incentive
for wine and RTD producers to produce low alcohol drinks.
However, it was pointed out that changes in excise rates alone
are not enough to control the abuse of alcohol. For example, the increase in
the consumption of RTDs can be attributed to a number of factors such as a
reduction in price. Additional factors that influence consumption are marketing
and the general drinking patterns of specific groups in society. An example is
the preference that young women have for spirits.
The Committee is also of the view that future changes to
legislation that impacts on the taxation of alcohol should be preceded by a
comprehensive inquiry into the taxation of alcohol products.[184]
5.37
The
Committee still considers that such a review would have significant merit.
Debit Taxes
5.38
A
'debit tax' is essentially a tax on bank transactions, particularly withdrawals
and transfers. The Debit Tax Council describes the debit tax in the following
terms:
The Debit Tax formula
is simply an added percentage, one third of one percent (0.33%) is suggested,
to the amounts withdrawn from all accounts held in trust by banking and
financial institutions. This Tax, when cleared is instantly deposited through the
Electronic Funds Transfer (EFT) system by way of the banking and financial
institutions computers into the National Treasury at the end of each day.[185]
5.39
The
Committee received a number of submissions calling for the introduction of a
broad debit tax by the Commonwealth.[186]
5.40
Such
taxes have been implemented in Australia. An example is the Bank Account Debits
Tax, (BAD Tax), which is in the process of being phased out across Australia. However,
submissions to this inquiry sought to introduce a debit tax as the single form
of Commonwealth taxation. They proposed that all other forms of Commonwealth
tax be repealed, and the debit tax asserted in their place.
5.41
Supporters
of the debit tax advance the argument that a debit tax, levied at a very small
rate would generate immense amounts of revenue. Claims include the following:
-
A 1%
debit tax would bring in 3 times the revenue any government needs to get our
nation out of trouble ($520 billion per year), enough to run all current
Government programs, and also generate many more jobs, pay off our foreign debt
and improve our hopsitals. It will also save billions in tax collecting costs.[187]
-
A
debit tax of 1% would amount to revenue of $300 billion annually. This
compares favourably with the actual figure of $187 billion using all its
complexities and compliance costs.[188]
-
it
would almost triple government tax revenue.[189]
5.42
Supporters
argue that debit taxes would provide a range of advantages over current
arrangements. A sample of these are as follows:
-
No tax
cheating or tax avoidance necessary or possible.[190]
-
because
the tax is payable each time money changes hands, the rash of speculative
investment which is rife today would not be profitable. Instead, more
investment would be in the real economy which is jobs for everyone![191]
-
multinationals
would have to pay their fair share of taxation[192]
-
all
employees would immediately have a larger take home pay packet, no income take
deducted. More money to spend.[193]
5.43
The
Committee does not find merit in proposals for a debit tax. In order to explain
the Committee's view, it is useful to consider what the Committee would
describe as the two key debit tax myths: the 'myth of increments' and the 'myth
of compliance'.
The myth of increments
5.44
One
key argument put forward by supporters of debit taxes is that the tax as a
percentage would be so small usually a fraction of a percent that it would
barely be noticeable, yet over time it would result in the production of
massive revenue. This myth is premised on a simple multiplication exercise, as
follows.
5.45
Wholesale
payments (including high value trading transfers) in the Australian banking
system amount to around $135 billion per day, or over $49 trillion per year.[194] If this
figure is multiplied by some commonly suggested debit tax rates, the following
products result:
Debit tax rate (%)
|
Product ($b)[195]
|
0.33
|
162.6
|
0.5
|
246.4
|
1
|
492.8
|
5.46
Total
government revenue for the 2004/05 budget was estimated at $193.2 billion.[196] So, even
making the unlikely assumption of absolute compliance with the system, a tax
rate of approximately 0.392% would be necessary to maintain parity with current
revenue.
5.47
Unfortunately,
most analysis of the debit tax stops at this point. A tax rate of 0.392%
appears to be attractive, especially to taxpayers used to paying income tax
rates. There is an assumption that the rate is so tiny, it would barely be
noticeable. The Debit Tax Council's literature, for instance, cites as an
advantage of the debit tax system the proposition that 'because of the very
large amount of withdrawals, only a very small amount is required as debit
tax.'[197]
5.48
However,
while the debit tax may indeed result in small percentages of tax being paid on
individual transactions, an analysis on a 'per transaction' basis does not
appear to be particularly useful. Governments, companies, and even individuals
are much more likely to assess their tax contribution over the space of a full
year, and in each full year they may have thousands of transactions. So, while
the per transaction cost may be small, their annual tax bill may be large.
5.49
As
noted above, if a 1% debit tax were applied, and full compliance were achieved,
the projected revenue (adopting the Debit Tax Council's formula) could
hypothetically be $492.8 billion annually. This would amount to nearly two thirds of GDP. Whether the $492.8
billion dollars is collected in tiny increments or one lump sum is entirely
irrelevant. The result is still a national tax bill amounting to two thirds of
GDP.
5.50
This
logic may be extended to companies. Proponents of the debit tax appear to
consider that, because the debit tax is so small on a per-transaction basis,
companies will not endeavour to avoid it:
[Multinational
corporations] (and foreign investors) wil be more than excited about this tax
system as there will be no more company tax or income tax imposed on them and
their shareholders.[198]
5.51
In
reality, however, companies are also likely to consider their tax burdens on an
annual basis. If debit taxes were levied directly upon companies, then the
amount of tax paid would be reported annually, and would be likely to result in
a significant figure (given that debit taxes would constitute the whole field
of taxation). When the tax burden is considered annually, the fact that it is
paid in tiny increments is irrelevant.
5.52
As
debit taxes are collected from within the banking system, the 'tax bill' for
companies would likely emerge in the form of increased banking fees, as banks
seek to recoup the tax withdrawn from their system. However, whether the tax is
paid directly or in the form of fees to banks, it is unlikely to escape notice.
5.53
Finally,
it has been demonstrated that, even on a per-transaction basis, the amount of
debit tax will often be significant. This is because the debit tax is a cascading tax. Every time money changes
hands, another layer of debit tax would be added:
A Cascading Tax, such
as the Debit Tax would be, causes the effective tax rate to increase, depending
on the number of times a good changes hands before it is purchased. This is
largely due to the cost of the Debit Tax being added after the profit margin is
added. In the production [of a good as ] simple as pencils it is estimated that
at least five withdrawals would be made. With more complex production, even
more withdrawals and profit margins would be included. [] In the end, it is not
the companies that are most affects, but the consumer.[199]
5.54
In a
modern, complex banking system, this cascading effect can add a substantial
number of 'layers' of taxation for apparently simple transactions:
To see how these
transactions arise consider the following example: I draw a cheque for $10 000
on my ANZ account to buy a car. The car dealer deposits the cheque with his
Westpac account. Through the payments system Westpac presents the cheque to the
ANZ and draws down its value against the ANZ's balances. That drawing down of
funds is a new debit in the system. Now ANZ head office is going to debit the
funds standing in the Canberra branch. To cover that the Canberra branch may
have to draw down its balances elsewhere in the system. All of a sudden we now have
4 debits recorded. It gets even more complex if the car buyer draws on a Credit
union which itself banks with the ANZ.[200]
Conclusion
5.55
The
fact that the debit tax on single transactions may be small is irrelevant to an
assessment of the overall impact of the tax on the economy and on companies and
individuals paying their tax. Simply put, the many small tax payments add up. They
add up even more quickly when debit taxes 'cascade' as the transactions
involved in the production of goods and the operation of the banking system
combine.
The myth of compliance
5.56
Another
major advantage proferred by supporters of debit taxes is that they would be
impossible to avoid. This is simply not so. The Committee can observe three
different methods which could easily be used to get around the debit tax. All
three arise from the central principle of taxpayers seeking to reduce the
amount of taxable activity they undertake (in this case, reducing their
exposure to bank withdrawals and transfers).
The use of cash
5.57
If a
debit tax were introduced, one likely outcome would be a substantial increase
in the number of cash, in-kind and bartered transactions undertaken. Cash
transactions would not avoid debit tax altogether, as the cash would still be
taxed as it was withdrawn from the financial institution. However, once it
leaves the financial institution, cash inevitably passes through a series of
transactions before finding its way back to a bank. These transactions would be
untraceable and unenforceable under a debit tax system. A study in 1998 made
the following observation:
companies may
decide to keep cash on hand to pay employees, or pay through in-kind
vouchers. In Woolworths' case, approximately 80,000 people are employed by the
supermarket chain. If an employee earns the average wage of $712 per week, an
internal contract may be set up so that the employee receives $612 in wages and
$100 of in-kind vouchers. If all employees received this, both Woolworths and
the employees would save over $1.3 million each year by not actually entering
the money flow and encountering a debit tax.[201]
5.58
Small
businesses, particularly in the retail and services sectors, with ready access
to cash payments, would almost certainly retain this cash instead of banking
it. The cash could then be used to pay for business expenses (including wages).
It would be effectively untraceable because, even under current circumstances,
the Payments System Board acknowledge that 'the number and value of cash
payments is very difficult to measure'.[202]
Vertical integration
5.59
Another
simple way for large companies to reduce their exposure to the banking system
(and therefore to the debit tax) would be to decrease the number of
transactions they conduct with outside companies. One excellent way to achieve
this would be through vertical integration of their companies. If single
corporations own the means of production, distribution and sale for their goods
and services as far upstream and as far downstream as possible, then the
'transactions' between those business units can be managed through the
company's own accounting and management structures:
Vertical integration
would benefit both the companies, the subsidiaries, and the consumers by
skirting around the money market using cash, in-kind or internal contracts.[203]
5.60
On
the other hand, if companies focus on their 'core' activities and contract with
upstream suppliers and downstream customers who are external to the
corporation, then every transaction, at every stage of production, will add a
cascading layer of debit tax.
5.61
This
tax-based pressure to integrate vertically may then reduce the competitiveness
of companies, and of the economy generally, as suppliers will no logner need to
innovate and compete to attract contracts their customers will be in house,
and the tax system will inhibit their customers from looking for other options.
Changes to banking behaviour
5.62
In
the modern economy, where capital can flow quickly and easily around the world,
one simple way for large corporations to reduce exposure to debit taxes would
be to conduct banking offshore. In fact, faced with the massive increases in
bank fees likely as a result of debit taxes, the banks themselves may find it
attractive to conduct their wholesale operations offshore. This behaviour would
not completely avoid debit tax (as debit tax would still apply once funds were
repatriated), but it may reduce the number of 'layers' of debit tax which apply
as a result of wholesale transactions in the banking system.
Conclusion
5.63
The view
that compliance is guaranteed under a debit tax system is unsubstantiated. In
fact, tax avoidance under a debit tax system would be a relatively simple
matter, with opportunities for avoidance at all levels from the largest
companies (through vertical intergration and offshore banking) to the individual
(by using cash).
5.64
Low
levels of compliance would reduce the amount of revenue obtained under the
debit tax. This would leave governments with two options to raise the rate of
debit tax, (thereby increasing the incentive for others to avoid paying it) or
to introduce other forms of taxation (ending the notion of the debit tax as a
universal taxation system).
Conclusion in relation to debit taxes
5.65
Despite
being collected incrementally, debit taxes would be noticeable by companies and
taxpayers. Debit tax would be simple to avoid, and would therefore generate an
uncertain amount of revenue. The 'debit tax concept' has a range of supporters,
and has been advanced from time to time for at least a decade. While the
Committee expects that debit taxes will retain a certain amount of support,
they do not provide a realistic basis for a taxation system.