Chapter 5
Horizontal fiscal equalisation
5.1
Another common problem for federations is the uneven capacity of
jurisdictions at the same level of government, such as states or provinces, to
provide the same level of services to their communities. Most federations
address this problem through some form of Horizontal Fiscal Equalisation (HFE);
a form of financial assistance that allows governments to reduce the
inequalities in the capacities of sub-national governments arising from the
differences in their geography, demography, natural endowments and economies.
5.2
Australia has had mechanisms in place to provide for HFE since the
establishment of the Commonwealth Grants Commission in 1933.[1]
Its objective is to provide full equalisation in a way that gives each of the
six states, the Australian Capital Territory and the Northern Territory the
same per capita fiscal capacity to provide services and the associated
infrastructure to their residents.[2]
According to the Commonwealth Grants Commission (CGC) this means that:
State governments should receive funding from the goods and
services tax revenue such that, if each made the same effort to raise revenue
from its own sources and operated at the same level of efficiency, each would
have the capacity to provide services at the same standard.[3]
5.3
Currently the funds distributed to achieve HFE are the revenues raised
from the Goods and Services Tax (GST). The distribution of GST required to
achieve HFE is decided by the Commonwealth Treasurer each year, on the basis of
advice provided by the Commonwealth Grants Commission (CGC).[4]
Distribution: Legislation and Commonwealth Grants Commission
5.4
The main point of contention around HFE is the extent to which GST
revenue is redistributed among the States and Territories compared with an
equal per capita distribution. Under the Federal Financial Relations Act
2009 and preceding legislation governing distribution of the GST revenue,
each state and territory's share is calculated using 'relativities' designed to
ensure that each state has the same financial capacity (not necessarily the
same total quantum or per capita quantum) to provide services to its residents.[5]
There is no obligation on the states to provide the services for which these
payments are funded.[6]
5.5
The specific calculation is reached by multiplying each state and territory's
'adjusted state population' by the available pool of GST revenue, and then
dividing that product by the sum of the adjusted state populations of all of
the states for the payment year. Thus:
Adjusted state population x GST
revenue

Adjusted total population
5.6
'Adjusted State population' means the 'estimated population of the State
on 31 December in the payment year...multiplied by the GST revenue sharing
relativity...for the State for that year.'[7]
5.7
The 'GST revenue sharing relativity' is defined as being that determined
in a legislative instrument by the minister after consulting each of the states
and territories.[8]
In practice, the relevant minister 'almost without exception, accepts the
[advice of the Commonwealth Grants Commission] ... and the Ministerial Council
for Commonwealth-State Financial Relations does not exercise its option to
dissent on the CGC's advice...The Commonwealth Treasurer allocates 100% of the
GST revenue...between States using CGC relativities.'[9]
5.8
In practice, the relevant Commonwealth minister refers the matter of
consulting with the states and territories and determining the appropriate
relativities to the Commonwealth Grants Commission (CGC).[10] Consistent with the intergovernmental
agreement (IGA) on Federal Financial Relations and the previous
Intergovernmental Agreement on the Reform of Commonwealth-State Financial
Arrangements,[11]
the CGC calculates relativities using a principle of Horizontal Fiscal
Equalisation.
Views on HFE in Australia
5.9
There were a range of views on dealing with the issues presented by
horizontal fiscal equalisation. It was generally acknowledged that Australia's
level of HFE was high but that this was to be expected given the corresponding
high vertical fiscal imbalance.
5.10
Dr Zimmermann and Mrs Finlay argued that:
[w]hile some level of equalization is broadly accepted as
being in the broader national interest and as the price of being a member of
the Federation, there does seem to be a point at which the costs outweigh the
benefits, the disincentives limiting growth-creating policies and investment
begin to negatively affect our future economic prosperity, and where there is a
real risk of a growing resentment amongst citizens in the fiscally stronger
States that may undermine national unity.[12]
5.11
The link between effective HFE processes and national unity was also
raised in the paper by the Business Council of Australia. They note that:
[a]s the Commonwealth comes increasingly to hold the purse
strings, another area of contention between Governments will grow. Australia
has a long history of horizontal fiscal equalisation, that is, adjustments in
the level of payments to the States to provide additional financial support to
those States thought to be in weaker financial positions. As States come to
rely more on financial support from the Commonwealth, the level of that support
will become an increasingly political issue.[13]
5.12
At the time of writing, there is some evidence to support the theory
that HFE can be a focus of political friction. Writing in The Australian
on 27 May 2011,
Henry Ergas, noted that:
The states' abject financial dependence on the commonwealth
causes constant conflicts and inefficiencies, while the redistribution of tax
revenues from richer to poorer states has reduced the states' incentive and
ability to adjust to changing circumstances.
It was therefore inevitable that a resource boom, shifting
the power balance between states and between the boom states and the
commonwealth, would cause trouble.
5.13
He goes on to argue that any reform of Australia's fiscal federalism
should be guided by 'two realities':
First, the policy of systematically redistributing wealth
between states was put in place during the Great Depression.
But already by the 1980s, income divergence between states
was one-third to one-half lower than it was in the 1930s.
And population mobility and a more flexible economy have
since reduced the spread in growth rates between the states by about one
percentage point per decade.
This fiscal redistribution has therefore largely lost its
purpose. It is now a form of middle-class welfare, in which West Australian
miners subsidise Tasmanian greenies and arts festivals in South Australia. And
worse, it is positively counterproductive.
Second, while being weaned off fiscal redistribution, the
states need more efficient revenue sources of their own.
An increase in the GST, offset by cuts in income taxes and in
inefficient state taxes, would be an important step in that direction.
Unfortunately, with all GST revenues flowing to the states, raising its rate
and widening its base is all pain, no gain from the commonwealth's perspective. [14]
5.14
Suggesting a way forward, the NSW Business Chamber proposed that:
the Australian Government should ask the Productivity
Commission to independently review the way in which the Commonwealth Grants
Commission manages the HFE process. In particular, the Productivity Commission
could investigate whether the “five pillars” adopted
by the CGC are the most appropriate framework within which to manage HFE. The
Commission could make recommendations on the models that preserve the principle
of HFE but incorporate it into a modern economic context. It is proposed that
such a review would be limited to the appropriateness of the distribution
formula, and not look at the split of responsibilities between State and
Federal Government or other fiscal transfers between the levels of Government
(such as NPPs).[15]
Incentives and disincentives
5.15
A key issue that needs to be considered is the issue of incentives embedded
in the HFE process for states and territories to maximise their revenue
raising.
5.16
The committee heard that the CGC has no remit to look at whether states
and territories should have raised as much revenue as they could. Rather, the
CGC aims to give all jurisdictions the same fiscal outcome. This matter was
highlighted in an exchange between a member of the committee Senator Chris
Back, and the Chair of the CGC, Mr Spasojevic:
Senator BACK: But it is not clear to me where in the
guidelines the states and territories should be aiming to act as responsibly
and effectively as possible to maximise revenue and contain expenditures.
Mr Spasojevic: I think those constraints fall outside
the gamut of what the commission is asked to do, in that if we think of the states
collectively we are asked to distribute a given amount of money amongst them.
We are not asked, for example, to determine what a good state policy or a good
state fiscal position is and distribute the GST to somehow make that happen. We
just give them all the same fiscal outcome. You may think that the states
should have a tighter or lower average outcome. It is beyond the commission to
comment on whether that is appropriate or not.[16]
5.17
The NSW government in their submission focused clearly on the way the
current HFE system works against increased efficiencies.
The HFE system is designed to flatten as much as possible the
differences between the states. Above average revenues are equalised away and
there is no incentive to improve efficiency. There is a disincentive against
expanding the revenue base, either through increasing activity in the state or
through undertaking additional expenditure to fund economic development, as the
increased revenue capacity will result in lower GST revenue.[17]
5.18
A slightly contrary point of view is put by the Tasmanian government.
They argue that the policy neutral stance of the CGC is actually a strength of
the system.
Without HFE, there would be much greater disparities in the
quality of life of Australians living in different states. The CGC process for
determining each state’s share of GST revenue is transparent, objective and
policy-neutral. It does not compensate states for any economic or financial
mismanagement, and states cannot directly affect their share of GST revenue.[18]
5.19
The differing position of the two states probably reflects the position
put by NSW that '[t]he consequences of Australia's attempt at total and
comprehensive fiscal equalisation are large cross-subsidies paid by the larger
to the smaller states.'[19]
This position is supported by Twomey and Withers who argue that the extent of
HFE 'provides greater disincentives for sub-national governments to seek and
provide efficient delivery of government services'. They advocate that, '[a]t a
minimum, more transparent and less complex equalisation processes with improved
incentives for efficiency could be developed.'[20]
Review of GST Distribution 2011
5.20
In 2010, the CGC completed a five-year review of its methodology and the
relativities used to formulate each state's share of the GST revenue. As a
result, the relativities being used from 2010-11 differ significantly for those
used for 2009-10, a change which contributes to the extent to which there have
been changes in the per capita redistribution of GST.
5.21
In the report of the review, the CGC recognised the complexity and
shifting nature of the landscape against which the GST is distributed:
This review recognises that the equalisation landscape has
been radically transformed. At the time of the 2004 Review, the two most
populous States — New South Wales and Victoria — had above average fiscal
capacities and together shared the cost of equalisation, while other States’ capacities
were below average, and the Northern Territory well below average. Now the two
most populous States lie close to average and the two faster growing States —
Queensland and Western Australia — have seen their fiscal capacities strengthen
relative to the other States at unprecedented rates and to historically high
levels. These four now share the cost of equalisation. The other four States —
South Australia, Tasmania, the ACT and the Northern Territory — remain below
average, with the Northern Territory still well below average.
Achieving equalisation in this environment, which sees the
strong and growing revenue capacities of Western Australia and Queensland
effectively shared with other States, requires a clearer recognition that this
level of, and growth in, revenue capacity also increases the need for those
States to spend to build the infrastructure required and acquire other assets
in keeping with their population growth. Both have to be adequately recognised
at the same time for equalisation to be achieved.[21]
5.22
On 30 March 2011, the Australian Government commissioned a review of the
distribution of revenue from the GST to the states and territories. This is
due to provide a final report by September 2012.
5.23
The Terms of Reference of the review acknowledge that Australia is
facing a number of long term trends that are driving pronounced and challenging
structural change in the economy, as well as ongoing challenges in tackling the
entrenched disadvantage of many Australians, especially indigenous Australians.[22]
It will consider, as part of its objectives and scope:
whether the distribution of the GST and the current form of
horizontal fiscal equalisation will ensure that Australia is best placed to
respond to these challenges and public confidence in the financial
relationships within the Australian Federation is maintained.[23]
Committee view
5.24
The Committee recognises that a mechanism to implement HFE is a long
standing feature of Australian federal-state relations and that it is widely
regarded as an essential component in managing Australia's national economy.
While long standing, the committee notes that HFE has been a highly
controversial element in federal-state relations and that this has generated
widespread debate over the need for reform. Given the intense nature of this
debate, the committee acknowledges that making improvements to the current
fiscal settings is neither easy nor likely to happen in the short term.
5.25
The committee notes, however, the Gillard Government's recently
announced review of the distribution of revenue from the Goods and Services Tax
to the States and Territories. The committee regards the review as an important
step in addressing many of the controversies that currently surround the
administration of the HFE arrangements in Australia. It considers however,
that the value of the review could be increased if its scope were expanded to
include an examination of the incentives for states and territories to increase
their revenue raising.
Recommendation 10
5.26
The committee recommends that the recently announced review into the
distribution of revenue from the Goods and Services Tax give particular
attention to the issue of incentives and disincentives to states and
territories to maximise their revenue.
Financial Assistance Grants – Local Government
5.27
A second, less high profile, HFE problem concerns the distribution of
Financial Assistance Grants (FAGs) among local governments. Mandurah City
Council explained what it sees as an inequity in the system for distributing
general purpose grant moneys to local governments:
Under the current distribution model, the General Purpose
grant component is apportioned by the Commonwealth Grants Commission to State
and Territory Grants Commissions on a per capita basis i.e. based on the
population of each State and Territory. However, when the intra-State
distribution occurs, these grants are then apportioned to Local Governments
based on the principles of full horizontal equalisation and the minimum grant.
As a result of the existing Commonwealth-State-Local
distribution method, outer metropolitan and inner regional Councils in populous
States such as NSW and Victoria automatically receive significantly larger
grants – up to five times the grant received by similar sized WA Councils -
regardless of their actual need.[24]
5.28
As an example, Mandurah compared the grant outcomes for three regional
cities of similar size: Shepparton, Coffs Harbour and Mandurah. Despite their
similar nature and populations, Mandurah's grant in 2006-07 was around $1
million, while the other two received closer to $5 million each.[25]
5.29
It was suggested that the CGC take on an expanded role in undertaking
national horizontal fiscal equalisation amongst councils, rather than merely
amongst states:
[t]he Commonwealth Grants Commission should introduce a
‘national distribution’ model, providing General Purpose grants directly from
the Commonwealth to Local Governments (bypassing the States), based on their
relative ‘need’ (horizontal equalisation), rather than their State’s
population. If the Australian and State Governments are serious about achieving
an equitable national distribution of funds to all Local Governments, then it
is only fair that each Council should be assessed against all other Australian
Councils when competing for FAGs funding, rather than against only those
Councils in their state.[26]
5.30
This would clearly represent a radical reshaping of local government
finance. Other submitters, including the Australian Local Government
Association (ALGA), did not address this issue. The committee expects that, as
ALGA represents all councils, including those that would stand to lose from
such a restructuring, it would not be in a position to reach a policy position
on the proposal. The committee recognises the issue that concerns Mandurah City
Council, and agrees that it is an issue that could be considered in more detail
by an inquiry directed specifically at the funding of local government. It
notes that ALGA and Mandurah City Council are both advocating such an inquiry.
5.31
The issue of the suitability of the current approach to general purpose
grants for local government was highlighted in an earlier 2008 Productivity
Commission report, Assessing Local Government Revenue Raising Capacity. The
Productivity Commission received submissions from a number of participants who
questioned the appropriateness of the existing arrangements for distributing
Commonwealth general purpose grants. While the Productivity Commission noted
that the appropriateness of the current distribution of financial assistance
grants was beyond the scope of their terms of reference, they did go on to note
that '[t]o the extent that full equalisation remains a policy objective of the
Australian Government there is a case for more work in this area.'[27]
Committee View
5.32
The committee recognises the concerns raised in submissions about the
absence of equalisation at the local government level and notes the various
suggestions for reform. Most of the proposed changes would have significant
impact on the funding received by local government, creating winning and losing
shires and municipalities in the process.
5.33
Nevertheless, the committee is of the view that the conclusion reached
by the Productivity Commission, and the position advocated by ALGA amongst
others has merit and that the issue requires closer investigation. Other
matters relating to local government are considered in chapter 6.
Recommendation 11
5.34
The Committee recommends that the Joint Standing Committee proposed in Recommendation
17 of this report be asked to inquire into the extent of and need for reform of
the arrangements for horizontal equalisation that currently exists between
local government shires and municipalities across Australia.
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page