Chapter 1

Chapter 1

Introduction: why does income inequality matter?

The form of law which I propose would be as follows: In a state which is desirous of being saved from the greatest of all plagues—not faction, but rather distraction—there should exist among the citizens neither extreme poverty nor, again, excessive wealth, for both are productive of great evil...Now the legislator should determine what is to be the limit of poverty or of wealth. (Plato)

Background

1.1        This inquiry is concerned with the extent of income inequality in Australia. Primarily, this relates to the gap between those with the highest and the lowest incomes in Australia, as well as the distribution of incomes across the wage-earning population. Secondly, the inquiry is focussed on the impact that this inequality has on specific disadvantaged groups in Australian society—those with low or no income. It is particularly concerned with the ability of these groups to access health services, housing, education and employment. Thirdly, the committee is directed to examine the likely impact of government policies on current and future income inequality, and the practical measures that government could put in place to alleviate income inequality.

1.2        By necessity, the committee has covered considerable terrain in this inquiry. The extent of income inequality and its effects and possible remedies relates to several policy areas, many of which involve all three levels of government. The committee has gathered evidence on personal and company taxation, wages and superannuation policy, social security payments, employment, the systems of public education and health (including mental health), transport, housing and indigenous affairs. Governments must recognise that just as the causes of income equality are varied and interconnected, so too will the solutions to addressing disadvantage require a multi‑pronged approach that considers both the short and the long-term costs and benefits.

1.3        This chapter preludes the content of later chapters by asking the key question; why does income inequality matter? There has been considerable discussion in recent years—both in Australia and overseas—about the extent, the causes and the impact of income inequality and what, if anything, should be done to address it. Various issues that relate to income inequality have been the subject of public debate in Australia in recent years:

1.4        This inquiry and report is therefore particularly timely and aims to provide some perspective to the Australian debate on a wide range of issues.

Why does income inequality matter?

1.5        Why inquire into the extent of income inequality in Australia? Should the gap between the richest and poorest and the distribution or spread of incomes across society be a matter of concern for government and policymakers? Does it matter that the average full-time adult Australian worker earns $78 878 per annum while the average compensation package for an Australian ASX 200 Chief Executive Officer is more than 60 times that amount at $4.84 million per annum?[11] Does it matter that this compensation package for an ASX 200 CEO is 145 times that of a worker on the minimum wage?[12] Would it matter if these differentials grew even further to a factor of 200, or beyond?

1.6        There are a range of views as to whether, and if so, why income inequality matters. The arguments run along political and ideological lines. At one pole are those who dismiss distributional concerns as a matter for the market to determine, not government. At most, they support a minimalist welfare system. At another pole are those who see inequality as morally problematic and who emphasise that a more equal society increases overall wellbeing.[13] There are various views between these positions:

Poverty, not inequality and the importance of economic growth

1.7        Some argue that income inequality should not and does not matter. Martin Feldstein, a Professor of Economics at Harvard University and a former adviser to United States President Ronald Reagan, has questioned the harm of the rich getting richer provided the incomes of others do not fall. He held that where the incomes of high-income individuals increase without decreasing the incomes of others, it should be regarded as a good thing as it satisfies the Pareto principle.[14] Feldstein described those who would object to this as 'spiteful egalitarians'. He claimed that it makes these people worse off just to see the rich getting richer and having 'the extra pain of living in a more unequal world'. For Feldstein, the real distributional problem is not inequality but poverty.[15] In other words, provided those at the bottom are looked after, the income and wealth at the top should not be of concern.

1.8        Many opponents of significant redistribution through the taxation and transfer system emphasise the distributive benefits of economic growth. The Nobel Prize‑winning economist Professor Robert Lucas, for example, has been widely quoted for the following comment made in a 2003 essay:

Of the tendencies that are harmful to sound economics, the most seductive, and in my opinion the most poisonous, is to focus on questions of distribution...

...[O]f the vast increase in the well-being of hundreds of millions of people that has occurred in the 200-year course of the industrial revolution to date, virtually none of it can be attributed to the direct redistribution of resources from rich to poor. The potential for improving the lives of poor people by finding different ways of distributing current production is nothing compared to the apparently limitless potential of increasing production.[16]

1.9        Australian academics and commentators have made similar arguments.[17] Mr Chris Berg, a commentator with the Institute of Public Affairs, has recently contended that the essential economic danger of the 21st century is not inequality but slow economic growth. He suggests that inequality is not of concern unless wealth has come through improper means:

No doubt some extreme incomes have come at the expense of the rest of society. In Russia the oligarchs have expropriated public wealth to become private wealth. In our liberal society, rent seeking or legal constructs like intellectual property can generate wealth at the expense of the rest of us.

But the issue in these cases is not the existence of the wealth but how it was taken. And the solution would be to close down the illegitimate means of acquiring that wealth.[18]

1.10      Similarly, Mr Peter Saunders from the Centre for Independent Studies has argued that income inequality is no bad thing provided it is not a result of fraud or coercion but of freely-taken decisions by people using their own money. He provides the following example:

Consider the world's top footballers who nowadays earn $250K or more per week. Why do they get this much? Because top clubs chase scarce talent to improve their team performance. Who pays for these huge salaries? Ultimately, the millions of people who want to watch these players and who are prepared to pay higher ticket prices and/or monthly Pay-TV subscriptions in order to do so. Who gains? Everyone: players, the clubs who employ them, the clubs' customers who want to watch them, and the taxpayer. Who loses? Nobody.[19]

1.11      Others have argued that while overall income inequality is of concern, it should not be a public policy objective in itself. Professors Peter Whiteford and Andrew Podger of the Australian National University explain this perspective as follows:

Inequality is a complex issue. It is affected by many factors, so that it can increase as a result of beneficial changes as well as socially undesirable ones, and can decrease because of changes that reduce overall social wellbeing as well as a result of socially desirable changes. A particular level of inequality may not therefore be suitable as a policy target per se as distinct from such specific objectives as alleviating poverty, increasing employment, achieving a fair taxation system or improving levels of participation and engagement in society. This is not to deny the importance of social solidarity and broader concepts of fair distributions of income and wealth, nor the usefulness of measures of overall inequality as indicators of likely social problems, but a specific level of overall inequality may not be well suited as a policy objective. What we should be concerned about is what specific factors have led to a change in inequality and what policy can do to address these specific causes.[20]

The harm caused by inequality and the need to address it directly

1.12      Recently, there have been prominent calls for governments to actively reduce income (and wealth) inequality through specific measures aimed at both ends of the income spectrum. This view stresses that the gap between the income and wealth of the poorest and the wealthiest can impact on the performance of the economy, the health of individuals, the cohesiveness of society and the proper functioning of the polity.

1.13      In 2009, Richard Wilkinson and Kate Pickett published their book The Spirit Level: Why More Equal Societies Almost Always Do Better. The authors argue that a range of social and environmental problems are more likely to occur in a less equal society: ill-health, violence, drugs, obesity, mental illness, long working hours and big prison populations.[21] Their basic argument is that the amount of inequality in a society matters. As they write:

The relationships between inequality and the prevalence of health and social problems...suggest that if the United States was to reduce its income inequality to something like the average of the four most equal of the rich countries (Japan, Norway, Sweden and Finland). The proportion of the population feeling they could trust others might rise by 75 per cent—presumably with matching improvements in the quality of community life; rates of mental illness and obesity might similarly be cut by almost two‑thirds, teenage birth rates could be more than halved, prison populations might be reduced by 75 per cent, and people could live longer while working the equivalent of two months less per year.[22]

1.14      A similar argument was put by Nobel laureate and Columbia University Professor Joseph Stiglitz in his 2012 book, The Price of Inequality. He highlighted the harm to individuals, the economy, society and the polity from significant income inequality in America. Part of Professor Stiglitz's argument in opposing the high concentration of wealth is the impact of the undue political influence of those that hold it:

Widely unequal societies do not function effectively, and their economies are neither stable nor sustainable in the long-term. When one interest group holds too much power, it succeeds in getting policies that benefit itself, rather than policies that would benefit society as a whole. When the wealthiest use their political power to benefit excessively the corporations they control, much-needed revenues are diverted into the pockets of a few instead of benefitting society at large.[23]

1.15      Professor Stiglitz also argued that a concentration of wealth is bad for the stability of the economy and its capacity to generate jobs. He claimed that the shortfall in aggregate demand—which leads to unemployment—can be blamed on 'the extremes of inequality'. He noted that those on high incomes (and in particular the top one per cent of income earners) tend to save a greater proportion of their income relative to lower income cohorts. Accordingly:

If that top 1 percent saves some 20 percent of its income, a shift of just five percentage points to the poor or middle who do not save...would increase aggregate demand directly by 1 percentage point. But as that money recirculates, output would actually increase by some 1½ to 2 percentage points. In an economic downturn such as the current one, that would imply a decrease in the unemployment rate of a comparable amount.[24]

1.16      Further, Professor Stiglitz argued that high inequality leads to a less efficient and productive economy. In particular, he claimed that failing to invest in infrastructure, basic research and education is the end result of a lopsided wealth distribution in society. As he put it: 'The more divided a society becomes in terms of wealth, the more reluctant the wealthy are to spend money on common needs...In the process, they [the rich] become more distant from ordinary people'.[25]

1.17      The Australian parliamentarian and economist, Dr Andrew Leigh, has argued that a strong democracy requires that people 'bump up' against those who are different from them. He put the view that the rich may not value the social safety net if they use different hospitals and schools, travel solely by private transport and live among those in their own income bracket. And if the poor are cut off from the rich, 'they may cease to understand how hard you have to work to create a successful business'.[26] Dr Leigh concluded his 2013 book Battlers and Billionaires with the following observation:

The past generation has seen great success for the Australian economy. We are more productive and entrepreneurial; more open to ideas, products and people from overseas. But at the same time, we have become more unequal. There are many things about the 1950s and 1960s that we would not want to keep, but it's worth trying to reclaim those high levels of equality. Too much inequality strains the social fabric, threatening to cleave us from one another.[27]

1.18      Some Australian commentators have noted the negative impact of inequality on economic performance, and the positive economic effect from lowering income inequality. Dr David Richardson of the Australia Institute told the committee:

...if we look around the world, countries that tend to be less unequal, such as Scandinavia, tend to have pretty high average standards of living; and Australia has been in that boat too. On the other hand, the United States is deteriorating in this score; their productivity performance is ordinary, as is much of Latin America and other places where you get extreme inequality.[28]

1.19      Dr Richard Denniss, the Australia Institute's Director, drew the committee's attention to the link between wages and productivity:

High wages drive productivity growth. This is economics 101: high wages drive productivity growth because, in a very low-wage company in a low‑wage country, there is no strong incentive to invest in labour-saving technology...

In the US, one of the reasons that their labour productivity is dragged down is that they have an incredible workforce employed in low-productivity domestic servitude. You do not find people in Norway, Switzerland and Sweden with a lot of full-time live-in help. But if the wage is really low, as it is in America, you will find a lot of people employed in that very low‑productivity task; whereas, in Australia, you will find a lot of middle‑class people have cleaners...[29]

1.20      The economic consequences of inequality have recently been identified in leading multilateral forums. In an address in London in May 2014, the Managing Director of the International Monetary Fund (IMF), Ms Christine Laguarde drew attention to the problem of inequality and its economic impact. She explained:

Fundamentally, excessive inequality makes capitalism less inclusive. It hinders people from participating fully and developing their potential. Disparity also brings division. The principles of solidarity and reciprocity that bind societies together are more likely to erode in excessively unequal societies. History also teaches us that democracy begins to fray at the edges once political battles separate the haves against the have-nots. A greater concentration of wealth could—if unchecked—even undermine the principles of meritocracy and democracy...

It is therefore not surprising that IMF research—which looked at 173 countries over the last 50 years—found that more unequal countries tend to have lower and less durable economic growth.[30]

1.21      One of the most influential books on economics in recent years is the French economist Professor Thomas Piketty's Capital in the Twenty-First Century, published in French in 2013.[31] A key part of Piketty's argument is that inequality is 'shaped by the way economic, social and political actors view what is just and what is not, as well as by the relative power of those actors and the collective choices that result'. In other words, the extent of inequality is a choice. A detailed historical account, Piketty's book focuses on two key forces for divergence in wealth: the higher rate of return on capital (relative to income) and the rise in managerial salaries. He advocates that:

The ideal policy for ending an endless inegalitarian spiral and regaining control over the dynamics of accumulation would be a progressive global tax on capital...[32]

Income is often not a well-defined concept for very wealthy individuals, and only a direct tax on capital can correctly gauge the contributive capacity of the wealthy.[33]

1.22      Princeton University Professor and New York Times columnist Paul Krugman wrote of Piketty's book:

...what’s really new about “Capital” is the way it demolishes that most cherished of conservative myths, the insistence that we’re living in a meritocracy in which great wealth is earned and deserved.

For the past couple of decades, the conservative response to attempts to make soaring incomes at the top into a political issue has involved two lines of defense: first, denial that the rich are actually doing as well and the rest as badly as they are, but when denial fails, claims that those soaring incomes at the top are a justified reward for services rendered. Don’t call them the 1 percent, or the wealthy; call them “job creators.”

But how do you make that defense if the rich derive much of their income not from the work they do but from the assets they own? And what if great wealth comes increasingly not from enterprise but from inheritance? What Mr. Piketty shows is that these are not idle questions. [34]

1.23      Certainly, some of Professor Piketty's arguments have been criticised, but even many of these criticisms recognise the need for redistribution. Professor Tyler Cowen, writing in Foreign Affairs, for example, observed that wealth taxes 'do not mesh with the norms and practices required by a successful and prosperous capitalist democracy'. Rather, Professor Cowen claimed a 'more sensible and practicable policy agenda' would include calls:

...for establishing more sovereign wealth funds...; for limiting tax deductions that noncharitable nonprofits can claim; for deregulating urban development and loosening zoning laws, which would encourage more housing construction...; for offering opportunity grants for young people; and for improving education.[35]

Addressing the causes and consequences of income inequality

1.24      Australian governments have prioritised reforms that increase prosperity and allow its benefits to be shared. In their rhetoric, both the major Australian political parties emphasise sharing the benefits of growth and providing for most disadvantaged.[36] However, Australian governments have not viewed the reduction of income inequality as a specific policy objective.[37] Nonetheless, governments do recognise the importance of distributing income and wealth across the income spectrum. As the current federal Treasurer, the Hon. Joe Hockey MP, told the Sydney Institute in May 2014:

Official data shows average real household disposable income has gone from $540 per week in 1994 to over $820 per week now – that means the average Australian household is almost $290 per week better off today in real terms than they were around two decades ago. And this growth has been broadly based across society. Household wellbeing across the community has grown significantly in the last two decades. And while much focus has been on the “rich getting richer”, the more accurate story is the fact that everyone is getting richer as a result of economic development. Few countries can tell this story.[38]

1.25      A principal policy objective of the Australian Treasury is to ensure that appropriate economic reforms are made to increase the productivity of the economy. While Treasury recognises the importance that the benefits of this productivity are broadly shared, it is not prescriptive on what the shape of this distribution should be. A 2013 Treasury paper on income inequality explained:

There is no clear consensus on what an acceptable level of income inequality is. Societies will choose how much inequality they allow according to the institutions, norms, laws, policies and programs they adopt.

In Australia, like other [Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development] nations, there has been a trend towards greater income inequality since the mid-1990s, but there has also been very strong growth in incomes across the board, including the bottom decile of households.

As Stiglitz, Sen and Fitoussi (2009) from the Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress have said: ‘If average income is increasing but at the same time inequality is increasing, it is not clear whether societal well-being is increasing or decreasing’.[39]

1.26      In 2002, the former Secretary of the Treasury and author of the 2010 Tax Review, Dr Ken Henry, wrote:

Even supposing income inequality had increased slightly over the second half of the 1990s, should this be of concern to economic policy makers? The answer to this question is not clearcut. Importantly, there is no clear consensus on what an acceptable level of inequality is ... Moreover, the policy lesson to be drawn from a reform-induced widening of income inequality is not obvious. Policy makers are very likely to believe that the market liberalising reforms of the past couple of decades in Australia have contributed to rising average incomes, and that the income gains have been widely shared. Is anybody seriously suggesting that those reforms should be reversed, in the certain expectation of significantly reduced average incomes and the highly speculative hope of a more egalitarian distribution of a smaller cake?[40]

1.27      Interestingly, there was no mention of the term 'income inequality' in the final report of the Henry Tax Review.[41]

Addressing income inequality through the tax and transfer system

1.28      Beyond prioritising economic growth, Australia shares with many other countries a broad political consensus on a legislated minimum wage, a progressive taxation system, the provision of a social safety net and public investment in health and education. As chapter 2 of this report explains in more detail, Australia's tax‑transfer system is well-targeted and has been effective in reducing income inequality. A 2008 Treasury paper on Australia's tax and transfer system stated:

Spending on the transfer system by the Australian Government amounted to over 25 per cent of revenue collected in 2006-07. Transfers provide financial assistance to individuals who are unable, or not expected, to fully support themselves, and to families to help meet the costs of raising children.

The net effect of the personal tax-transfer system is to reduce the incomes of higher income households, and increase the incomes of lower income households (see Chart 7.2). The combined effect of taxes and transfers is to make the distribution of income across households more equal. The [Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS)] reports that there was no significant change in income inequality from the mid-1990s to 2005-06 (ABS 2007d). This is despite a more pronounced increase in private incomes at higher income levels than the increases for those on low and middle incomes.[42]

1.29      There has been considerable conjecture in Australia, as in other countries, about the level and thresholds of taxation, and the level and thresholds for benefits. A lot of political debate has focused on which people in society are most deserving of welfare payments. There have been successive media campaigns since the 1970s raising doubts as to whether unemployment benefit recipients are deserving of the payment. As noted above, this has more recently been directed at recipients of the Disability Support Pension.

1.30      The recent federal budget has again fuelled debate as to whether the current level of redistribution is fair. As the Treasurer stated a few weeks after the federal budget:

Payments are too broadly available to too many people. As a result, less is available for those most in need. At the moment over half of Australian households receive a taxpayer funded payment from the government...

To put it in perspective, around one in ten households (roughly 13%) rely entirely on the government for household income. Thirteen per cent of young Australians receive Youth Allowance. Over seventy percent of Australians over 65 receive the Age or Service Pension. And more than one in twenty working age Australians receive the Disability Support Pension. So we have a very comprehensive welfare system. But it should not be taboo to question whether everyone is entitled to these payments...

This year the Australian government will spend on average over $6,000 on welfare for every man, woman and child in the country. Given that only around 45 per cent of the population pays income tax, the average taxpayer must pay more than twice this amount in tax to fund welfare expenditure. In other words the average working Australian, be they a cleaner, a plumber or a teacher, is working over one month full time each year just to pay for the welfare of another Australian. Is this fair?[43]

1.31      Governments address income inequality not just through direct payments but also through the provision of taxpayer-funded services. In a speech to business economists in May 2014, the current Treasury Secretary Dr Martin Parkinson noted:

After we factor in taxes and transfers, income inequality has increased only slightly in Australia over the past two decades against the backdrop of very strong growth in incomes across the entire income distribution. This means that the income gains we've enjoyed over the past two decades have been shared much more broadly [than in the United States].

This reflects, among other things, the access provided right across the community to good quality education, training and healthcare. These are the essential pre-requisites to securing well paid employment. A key motivation for the Government in shaping the Budget has been reinforcing sustainability and access to high quality health and education well into the future.[44]

1.32      This inquiry focuses on the interplay between income inequality and access to education, housing, education, transport and work. It recognises that an analysis of income inequality in isolation does not measure the benefit to the individual or family from accessing these services. In this report, the committee acknowledges the supplement that these services should provide in addition to a wage and income support payments, but also the impact that having a low income may have in being unable to access these services (see chapter 3).

What do Australians think about income and wealth redistribution?

1.33      Another way of thinking about whether income inequality matters is to consider the public's view. Indeed, the level and types of taxation and redistribution are inherently democratic questions. It is the public that should determine what a 'fair' society looks like.

1.34      Figure 1.1 shows that only 1 in 5 people surveyed over the past decade believe that income and wealth should not be redistributed. Roughly half of those surveyed over the past decade believe that income and wealth should be redistributed.

1.35      Figure 1.2 shows that over the past decade, the proportion of people favour less tax over more spending on social services has ranged from 34 to 42 per cent. The proportion favouring more social services over less tax has ranged from 30 to 47 per cent. The longer-term picture is of declining support for the option of 'less tax' and greater support for 'more spending on social services'.

Figure 1.1: Should wealth and income be redistributed?

Source: School of Politics and International Relations, Australian National University, Trends in Australian political opinion: Results from the Australia Election Study 1987–2013, p. 55. For income and wealth should be redistributed, estimates combine ‘strongly agree’ and ‘agree’. For income and wealth should not be redistributed, estimates combine ‘disagree’ and ‘strongly disagree’.

Figure 1.2: Less tax or more social services?

Source: School of Politics and International Relations, Australian National University, Trends in Australian political opinion: Results from the Australia Election Study 1987–2013, p. 54. For 'favours less tax', the response categories are (1987-2013) ‘strongly favour reducing taxes’ and ‘mildly favour reducing taxes’. For 'favours spending more on social services', the response categories are (1987-2013) ‘mildly favour spending more on social services’ and ‘strongly favour spending more on social services’.

Australia's system of social security payments

1.36      In the first decade of Federation, the seminal Harvester Judgment of 1907 established a system of high minimum wages in Australia. The judge of the Commonwealth Conciliation and Arbitration Court, Justice Henry Higgins, found that wages at a Melbourne factory (the Sunshine Harvester Company) should be based on the cost of living for a worker and his family. The test of a fair and reasonable wage was 'the normal needs of the average employee regarded as a human being living in a civilized community'. The Harvester Judgment established that Australia's minimum wage should be based on what is fair and reasonable rather than what the employer was offering or the capacity of industry to pay.[45]

1.37      The Harvester Judgment was fundamental to establishing a minimalist welfare system in Australia. In 1985, the Australian academic Professor Frank Castles used the term 'wage-earner's welfare state' to describe Australia's system of wage and support payment.[46] This model of social protection was characterised by high minimum wages, a male dominated labour force, extremely low unemployment, easy access to owner-occupied housing and a selective system of welfare state benefits that was almost wholly non-discretionary in character.[47]

1.38      Australian households in the 21st century are significantly more complex and diverse to those catered to by the Harvester Judgment and Australia's pre-1970s welfare system. Different family structures, multiple careers in a lifetime, a significantly higher female labour market participation rate, longer life expectancy and mass-tertiary education have all challenged policymakers to adapt. As the Hon. Susan Ryan AO, the Age Discrimination Commissioner, recently noted:

Gone are the days when the typical structure of Australian households involved a male breadwinner and female homemaker, with the male spending his working life in one job before retiring, worn out, at the age of 65, and conveniently dying not too much later.[48]

1.39      Over the past century, welfare benefits and social protection programs in Australia have been incrementally introduced, amended and rebadged. The aged pension was introduced nationally in 1909 followed by invalid pensions in 1910 and a maternity allowance in 1912. From 1940, aged pensions were automatically adjusted for movements in the Consumer Price Index (CPI). A family allowance (child endowment) was introduced in 1941, a widow's pension the following year, and unemployment benefits in 1945. In 1973, a supporting parent's benefit was introduced followed by a handicapped child's allowance in 1974. In 1976, all pensions were automatically indexed to the CPI and a new family allowance payment replaced the child endowment. In 1983, a family income supplement was enacted followed in 1985 by a carer's pension and the Home and Community Care Program. Various large-scale childcare and labour market programs were introduced in the 1980s and 1990s. Compulsory superannuation was introduced in 1992. Since the mid-1990s, behavioural conditions have been placed on payments: in 1998, the 'Work for the Dole' Scheme was first enacted; in 2006, income management was introduced. One of the most significant recent social reforms, the National Disability Insurance Scheme, was legislated in 2013.

1.40      In 2014, the main income support payments are:

The context of this inquiry

1.41      As noted, this inquiry comes at a time of renewed interest in issues of wealth and income distribution both in Australia and internationally. Internationally, the debate has been fuelled by a combination of influential writings from economists such as Piketty and Stiglitz and public statements from prominent figures and organisations. In January 2014, the World Economic Forum's Global Risk report argued that that 'the chronic gap between the incomes of the richest and poorest citizens is seen as the risk that is most likely to cause serious damage globally in the coming decade'.[49] These concerns with extent and the impact of income inequality have also been identified by the IMF, United States President Barack Obama, media baron Rupert Murdoch and Pope Francis.[50]

1.42      In January 2014, the Australia Institute and Australia21 convened a roundtable to discuss how Australia should respond to growing inequality. It brought together a range of academics, welfare and public health advocates, union representatives, economists and parliamentarians.[51] The roundtable and its findings will be discussed in later chapters of this report.

1.43      The debate on income inequality in Australia has also been stimulated by the federal government's proposed budget measures and its review into the welfare system.

The 2014 federal budget

1.44      The terms of reference for this inquiry direct the committee to examine the likely impact of the changes proposed in the 2014–15 Budget. While chapter 5 of this report examines some of the Social Services measures in more detail, an outline of some of the key Budget measures is useful here.

1.45      The key social security measures in the Budget include proposals to:

1.46      Some of the proposed changes to FTB have passed the Parliament and become law.[52] Most of the other measures have been incorporated into other bills, which are currently before the Parliament.[53]

The McClure Review

1.47      In December 2013, the Minister for Social Services, the Hon. Kevin Andrews MP (Minister), commissioned a review of Australia's welfare system to identify improvements to ensure the social support system is sustainable, effective and coherent, and encourages people to work. An independent Reference Group, comprising Mr Patrick McClure AO (Chair), Ms Sally Sinclair and Mr Wesley Aird, was appointed to conduct the review.[54]

1.48      The Reference Group was asked to advise the Minister on how the welfare system can:

1.49      In June 2014, the Reference Group's Interim Report proposed four pillars of reform:

1.50      As of early September 2014, the Review had received 227 submissions in response to the Interim Report.[57]

The Australia21 Report

1.51      In April 2014, the Australia Institute and Australia21 published Advance Australia Fair? What to do about growing inequality in Australia. The report, provided to the committee as an attachment to Australia21's submission, details the proceedings and findings of the January 2014 roundtable on the subject of income inequality. The report's foreword states:

For some time Australia21 has been concerned that our political leaders are addressing neither the fact nor the implications arising from the fact that income inequality has been growing rapidly in Australia. On 31 January 2014 Australia21, in collaboration with the Australia Institute and the gracious support of Andrew Leigh MP, convened a roundtable discussion in Parliament House, Canberra to consider how Australia should respond to this growing inequality.[58]

1.52      The report's Executive Summary makes the following points:

1.53      In terms of the need for this national conversation, the report suggested that:

A media outlet might be encouraged and possibly subsidised to publish a series of in-depth articles to inform the Australian people about the extent of the problem and actions to address it over the next six months.[60]

The conduct of the inquiry

Submissions

1.54      The committee called for submissions by 22 August 2014. It received 64 submissions mainly from academics, peak stakeholder organisations and welfare agencies. The committee thanks all those individuals and organisations who made a submission to this inquiry.

1.55      The committee thanks The Treasury, the Productivity Commission, the Australian Council of Trade Unions, Professor Peter Whiteford of the Australian National University, Professor Peter Saunders from the University of New South Wales, the Bankwest Curtin Economics Centre and Taylor Fry Consulting Actuaries for their permission to reproduce the tables and figures in this report. 

Public hearings

1.56      The committee conducted seven public hearings in the course of this inquiry:

1.57      Unfortunately, time did not allow for hearings in Sydney and Darwin. The committee did schedule a hearing in Sydney which was unfortunately cancelled and moved to Canberra due to the Senate being recalled.

Site visits

1.58      Following the public hearings, the committee conducted site visits in Elizabeth and Rockingham. In Elizabeth, the committee visited Northern Futures Inc., a not-for-profit organisation focused on improving the employability of people across the northern Adelaide region (covering a population of 300 000 people). The Chief Executive Officer, Ms Gail Sulicich, and Board member, Mr Kelvin Trimper, explained some of the programs that Northern Futures is funded to operate to secure employment for the long-term unemployed in the region. She noted the success of some programs—such as the Skills for Jobs in Regions—in placing long-term unemployed people into pre-employment training programs. These programs have led these individuals to develop some of the basic skills that make them job-ready.

1.59      Ms Sulicich told the committee that an important part of her organisation's role is to discuss with employers in the region what job applicants need to do to gain employment. She noted that Northern Futures had gained a good reputation for finding employment for young people, mature-age workers and retrenched workers. However, it faced ongoing challenges in terms of ensure the long-term viability of its programs.

1.60      Following this meeting, the committee met with representatives of the Building Family Opportunities (BFO) Program, run by Wesley UnitingCare Port Adelaide. This program seeks to:

[B]ring together long-term jobless families, local community organisations, government, and employers to find solutions to complex issues that prevent families from participating in employment.

BFO case managers work with families to address all barriers until a sustainable job is achieved.[61]

1.61      Typically, an unemployed person is obliged to attend a Job Services Australia (JSA) provider who assists with finding work. The JSA support model centres around a regular 15 minute meeting which is quite administrative and mechanical, primarily focusing on job skills, experience and local job opportunities.  This process does not identify non-employment related constraints which may be preventing a person from finding and retaining sustainable employment. The BFO model invests more time in the individual. BFO case managers explained that by spending an hour (instead of 15 minutes) with an individual can assist in building trust, identifying constraints and then working on solutions allow a person to then enter employment with a greater chance of retaining this job. The BFO model requires a greater up-front investment but in the longer term ensures that these people are in sustainable employment and participating in society.

1.62      The Manager of Employment Services at Wesley, Ms Cherie Jolly, introduced five of her team members[62] to the committee noting their diverse training and backgrounds. Each member discussed their role in helping clients from often highly disadvantaged backgrounds achieve positive employment and training outcomes. Mr Peter Wall-Smith explained that his role as a mental health officer required him to liaise with local employers, identifying vacancies and job requirements. He would then seek to match his clients to these positions and accompany them to meet with prospective employers and seek feedback from the employer after the meeting. It is the case manager's ability to adapt and treat each client as an individual that has allowed BFO to succeed in placing long-term unemployed into jobs. Many JSAs have failed to get these outcomes.  

1.63      In Rockingham, the committee visited SMYL Community College where it met with the Chief Executive Officer Mr Sameh Gowegati and the school's principal Mr Tony McRae. The College is completing its fourth year of operation. Mr McRae explained to committee members the role of the school, the demographic and personal circumstances of students and some of the school's achievements and challenges. He noted that not all students came from a poor background but invariably the students' family situation was unsettled and often distressing. Mr McRae told the committee that the school has an impressive retention rate and that some of its students will progress to vocational and tertiary education.

1.64      The committee has the opportunity to visit the school's cooking facilities, where students are required to make meals for their peers. Breakfast is served from 8.15am from Monday to Thursday on schooldays. The committee then visited a nearby SMYL training facility where students undertake woodwork, metalwork, maintenance and welding, as well as acquiring skills in a charity retail shop and hairdressing salon. The training facility allows students to graduate with a Certificate II qualification. The committee was most impressed by SMYL's school and training facilities in Rockingham. It is important that these ventures are able to obtain long-term funding to ensure that the significant benefits of their work can continue.

1.65      The committee extends its sincere thanks to Ms Sulicich and her team at Northern Futures, Ms Jolly and her team at Wesley UnitingCare Port Adelaide, and Mr Gowegati and Mr McRae at SMYL Community Services in Rockingham. All three visits impressed the need for these organisations to be funded properly to undertake programs of vital community need. There also appears to be a need for greater engagement by State Government officials with these organisations to ensure that their crucial front-line work is not impeded by administrative and compliance requirements.

The structure of the report

1.66      This report has six chapters:

Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page