WARNING:
This Digest was prepared for debate. It reflects the legislation as
introduced and does not canvass subsequent amendments. This Digest
does not have any official legal status. Other sources should be
consulted to determine the subsequent official status of the
Bill.
CONTENTS
Passage History
Purpose
Background
Main Provisions
Endnotes
Contact Officer and Copyright Details
Workplace Relations Legislation
Amendment (Youth Employment) Bill 1998
Date Introduced: 26 November 1998
House: House of Representatives
Portfolio: Employment, Workplace Relations and Small
Business
Commencement: The operative provisions of
the Bill come into effect 28 days after Royal Assent.
The Bill amends the Workplace Relations Act
1996 and the Workplace Relations and Other Legislation
Amendment Act 1996 (the Principal Acts) to:
-
- promote the inclusion of junior rates in awards and workplace
agreements, and
-
- exempt junior wage rates from the anti-discrimination
provisions of the Workplace Relations Act.
The Bill does not directly legislate for a
reduction in existing youth wages but may have the effect of
encouraging the Australian Industrial Relations Commission (AIRC)
to insert new junior rates of pay in awards where they are not
presently in force.
Statistical and Theoretical
Issues
As at October 1998, the seasonally adjusted
unemployment rate for persons aged 15-19 years looking for
full-time work was 27.0%. The comparable figure for persons aged
over 20 years looking for full-time work is 7.1%.(1) The seasonally
adjusted figure for total unemployment was 7.7%.
Reasons for the comparatively high levels of
youth unemployment have been hotly debated for sometime and are
discussed below. In brief, the causes of youth unemployment are
ascribed to three factors:
-
- inadequate levels of total demand in the economy
-
- unsustainable levels of youth wages
-
- structural and technologically induced changes in the labour
market.
These are often portrayed as competing
explanations of a single phenomenon. However, like recent academic
commentators' suggestions for tackling unemployment generally,
youth unemployment is a multi-faceted problem,(2) probably
requiring a multi-pronged policy response.
It is beyond the scope of this Digest to analyse
these theoretical issues in depth. Reference, however, is made
below to a number of views canvassed recently, including in
official government publications. A series of tables and graphs is
included in the Appendix to help individual readers to make their
own assessments.
The statistical evidence presented offers
something of mixed picture. Over time there appears to be a strong
positive relationship with between levels of total
unemployment/levels of economic activity and levels of unemployment
amongst 15-19 year olds. For much of the past twenty years there
has been a ratio of about 3:1 between youth unemployment and total
unemployment. However, there have been departures from that ratio
and this suggests:
-
- the market for the employment of 15-19 year olds is fragile and
may be deteriorating (ie the ratio increases when the job market
weakens generally and the ratio appears to be widening in recent
times)
-
- generally a decline in total unemployment will cause a more
dramatic decline in youth unemployment rates.
This apparent link between levels of total
unemployment and youth unemployment tends to support the 'demand
effect' ('Keynesian') view of the world.
Other evidence presented in the Appendix,
however, provides support for the 'wage effect' (neo classical)
view that youth unemployment is largely attributable to youth wages
being too high. This view was reiterated recently in the context of
the Australian debate by a leading American economist, Professor
Dan Hamermesh of the University of Texas.(3)
Evidence presented in the Appendix would also
suggest that rises in youth wages tend to have a more pronounced
effect on the employment prospects of young females than of young
males. This is probably reflects labour market segmentation whereby
certain callings and trades are male dominated and others
characterised by a greater proportion of female employees, eg
retail services. In simplistic terms, a lift in the wages of a
young bricklayer is comparatively unlikely to see him replaced by a
45 year old male returning to full time employment. However, a
young female worker in sales appears to be more vulnerable to being
displaced by a mature female returning to the paid workforce from
full-time domestic duties and rearing a family.
Changes to the structure of the workforce and
the nature of work also have a part to play in accounting for high
rates of youth unemployment. This factor appears to be exhibited in
a further weakening in the youth labour market in relative terms
over the last two decades despite various training schemes, higher
(for the most part) retention rates in schools and tertiary
institutions and the continuation of junior award rates in many
industries.
Economic analyst, Ross Gittins, has described
these structural changes in the following terms:
The fundamental reason unemployment is somewhat
higher among teenagers is the dramatic decline in employer's demand
for young, unskilled, full-time labour. Over the past 15 years, the
number of full-time jobs held by teenagers has declined by 60
percent.
The main explanation for this is technological
change. Many of the menial jobs once done by teenagers are now done
by machines, and employers hire older and more highly educated
young people to work with those machines.
(Another development, however, is that many
menial jobs in retailing formerly done by full-time juniors have
been split into several part-time jobs. Over the past 15 years, the
number of part-time jobs held by teenagers has increased by almost
150 percent. For teenagers, there are almost twice as many
part-time jobs as full-time. Nearly two-thirds of these part-time
jobs are held by full-time students.)(4)
A further aspect of the current debate is that
there is a considerable gap between how the problem of youth
unemployment is perceived within the community and how it is viewed
by academic commentators and policy makers.(5)
For example, Gittins' comment that '1/4
unemployment is somewhat higher among teenagers...' would appear at
odds with wider community sentiment (see above).
Public concern at seemingly intractable(6)
'headline' levels of youth unemployment hovering in the vicinity of
30% is not surprising but is, in part, misconceived.
Most commonly cited statistics refer to the
proportion persons aged 15-19 years who are looking for full-time
work. The majority of the 15-19 cohort, are not in fact looking for
full-time work but are in full-time education and/or part-time
employment.
To be precise, as at October 1998, the 15-19
cohort comprised about 1 309 000 persons of whom:
-
- 562 500 were not in the labour force
-
- 213 900 were in full-time employment
-
- 395 980 were in part-time employment
-
- 70 800 were unemployed and looking for full-time work
-
- 66 000 were unemployed and looking for part-time work.
The latter two figures combined (full-time and
part-time unemployed) represent 18.3 percent of 15-19 year olds in
the labour force and 10.45 percent of the total 15-19 year old
group as a whole.(7)
Compounding any popular misconception about
youth unemployment are a number of what might be called
'qualitative aspects' of the public debate. Again, the treatment
here cannot be exhaustive and the issues are raised as a series of
questions to test (but not necessarily challenge) some of the
popular thinking about this problem.
-
- Given the unique nature of the labour market for persons aged
15-19 years as discussed above, is legislating of 'special
measures' to advantage the competitive position of this group
equitable? Is it more of a social 'tragedy' for a person aged 16
years but with no dependents to be unemployed, than it is for a 45
year old divorcee with a mortgage and two dependents to
support?
-
- Is too much emphasis placed on the difficulties of those who
have left formal education early, rather than on the 20-24 age
group which also experience higher than average levels of
unemployment (over 10 percent against a national average of just
under 8 percent)? Or is the plight of the 20-24 year old cohort
more deserving of attention given that it contains a greater
percentage of persons who have completed formal education and are
considering other options such as starting families, yet still
cannot find work? Is the 20-24 year old cohort more in need of
'special measures' when, in raw terms, there are 20 000 more
persons out of full-time work in this group than there are amongst
the 15-19 year old cohort seeking full-time work?
-
- How does one balance the net increase in economic welfare of
15-19 year olds who have work because of junior rates, against any
decline in the welfare of older workers who are displaced by such
younger persons? How does the retention and possible spread of
junior wage rates affect the economic welfare of young persons
already in work who may have their wages reduced (or their rate of
increase retarded) by the imposition of junior rates?
-
- To what extent are rising junior wage rates (see Appendix) a
product of changes in the age and skill mix within the 15-19 year
old cohort? Are junior wage rates rising because those full-time
jobs that remain for 15-19 year olds are amongst the more highly
skilled and more highly paid?
-
- To what extent would any spread in junior wages lower
unemployment amongst 15-19 year olds because of a resulting fall in
participation rates, ie fewer young persons would be attracted to
seeking full-time work?
-
- What proportion of the young unemployed are unemployable at any
market determined rate of pay, ie would they get a job even if they
worked for nothing?
The above are all complex and demanding
questions requiring the sort of empirical research and modelling
which could be expected in the course of a full public inquiry into
junior wage rates.
Constitutional and Legal
Constraints
It is generally accepted that the Commonwealth
Government and its agencies have prime responsibility for economic
management, including maintaining full employment. It is one of the
conundrums of Australian federalism that despite these
responsibilities, the federal Parliament has no express plenary
power to set wages of workers in the private sector. Other powers
are available but either untested or so constrained as to make
their use impracticable.
The Commonwealth's principal power over
workplace relations is the conciliation and arbitration power,
section 51(xxxv) of the Constitution. This provides that the
Commonwealth may legislate with respect to:
Conciliation and arbitration for the prevention
and settlement of industrial disputes extending beyond the limits
of any one State.
The Commonwealth Parliament does not have power
under section 51(xxxv) to legislate directly for rates of pay, nor
can the Parliament direct the AIRC as to the level of wages it
shall prescribe in making an award or industrial agreement.(8)
There is, however, no constitutional impediment
to the Parliament giving legislative guidance to AIRC as to what
factors it must take into account in making an award or other
determination. What the Parliament cannot do is prescribe a precise
formula for determining wages and conditions.
Successive governments have adopted the course
of seeking to influence the outcome of arbitral proceedings by
inserting various public interest criteria in the federal
industrial relations statute to assist the tribunal in reaching
decisions which accord with the Government's view of what may
constitute the public interest.
The Workplace Relations Act contains a number of
such provisions, including those:
-
- establishing the objects of the Act (section 3)
-
- governing the performance of the AIRC's functions generally
(section 88B)
-
- setting out a general public interest standard, providing
that:
sect.90 In the performance of its functions, the
Commission shall take into account the public interest, and for
that purpose shall have regard to:
...
-
- the state of the national economy and the likely effects on the
national economy of any award or order that the Commission is
considering, or proposing to make, with special reference to likely
effects on the level of employment and on inflation.
The current Bill would add to what is already an
expansive list of legislative signposts including subsection 3(a)
which states that one of the Act's objects is to encourage the
pursuit of high employment and other goals 'through higher
productivity and a flexible and fair labour market'.
The operative effect of such aspirational
provisions is a little uncertain. Each leaves the Commission with
considerable leeway to determine how such laudable but generally
stated objectives are to be met. Hence, the Government may take one
view as to what are good policies for reducing unemployment and
thereby promoting the objects of the Act, the AIRC may take
another. Similarly, the AIRC must give such provisions some weight
in its deliberations, but the Act cannot and does not prescribe how
much weight.
The proliferation of such 'public interest'
provisions runs the some risk of either unlawfully fettering the
tribunal's discretion or else sending it contradictory (or at best
ambiguous) signals on how it is to perform its work.
This Bill and the AIRC Inquiry
Introduction
As noted above, the object of this Bill is to
promote youth employment in part by retaining junior pay rates
prescribed in federal industrial awards. Also, by introducing a new
objective to the Workplace Relations Act, the Bill alerts the AIRC
to possible employment consequences for the employment of young
people arising from its decisions. The Bill affords credence to the
notion that junior rates are under threat, and questions arise as
to why this should be the case. Tentative answers are provided in
the next two sections.
The first section addresses junior pay rates in
an era of broader competency-based training and pay arrangements
applying to adults and trainees across large sectors of industry.
The second section looks at the barriers to age discrimination now
found in the federal industrial legislation. It looks at how age
discrimination provisions conflict with pay system provisions based
on the age of the junior, and, presumably, as well for 'adults'
where an adult is defined as being someone at or over the age 21
years. The Parliament has found solutions, albeit perhaps temporary
solutions to these problems. The Government now seeks to entrench
junior pay through this Bill.
Competency based training in industrial
awards
Since 1988 the major industrial parties
including the Australian Chamber of Commerce and Industry (ACCI,
formerly the Confederation of Australian Industry) representing
employers and the Australian Council of Trade Unions (ACTU)
representing unions, have moved many award classification and
training arrangements prescribed in industrial awards on to a
competency based or skills acquired system. This also involves the
establishment of consistent, skill based rates of pay.
At first, the move to competency was welcomed
indeed urged, by both union and employer organisations. (See:
Chapter 4 of Australia Reconstructed - ACTU-TDC Mission to
Western Europe, AGPS 1987, and Employer Perspectives on the
ACTU-TDC Report: Australia Reconstructed by the Confederation
of Australian Industry, 1987). In essence all parties recognised
that the old classification system (and pay structures) were no
longer adequate to meet the modern needs of industry.
Much of the rhetoric of the late 1980s by unions
to their members sought to win over support for 'multi-skilling' in
the event that access to (and provision of) training would allow
workers to move along career paths and access higher wages. To be
fair, the rhetoric has not been entirely wasted as workers have
come to appreciate that training for skills improvement
substantially enhances employability in what is appearing to many
to be a more volatile labour market than that which existed in the
1980s. An additional advantage of competency-based classifications
is that they are not discriminatory on other than 'relevant'
criteria - a point observed in the Joint Governments' Submission to
the AIRC's Junior Rates Inquiry(9) - the
governments include all State, Territory and Commonwealth
governments excluding Tasmania, Queensland and New South
Wales):
As well as being non-discriminatory, the main
advantage of skill-based classification structures is that they
create incentives for skill formation by ensuring that employees
capture the benefits of acquiring higher skills through higher
wages. And, to the extent that differences in the value of
employees is correlated with the skill and competency criteria used
to define progression through the wage scale, this addresses the
employment substitution effect ...(10)
Support for the transition to skills-based wages
was also required of the AIRC. An 'award restructuring' exercise
was attempted largely over the period 1988-1991 in respect of
federal industrial awards to remodel award classifications using
competency-based principles. It was facilitated through a new
principle devised by the AIRC, the Structural Efficiency Principle
(SEP). The SEP slim-lined award classifications and revamped duties
and training. It required award classifications to incorporate
prescribed competencies, detailed for each classification. Stepping
through the classifications via training and over time, was to
provide a career path where one may not have existed
previously.
The SEP continues to be recognised by the AIRC
in its Statement of Principles. These principles govern its
approach to making and varying awards.(11) The award restructuring
exercise was also strongly supported by the previous government,
evident in certain provisions of the Industrial Relations Act
1988 designed to modernise and review awards. The policy
objective was to broaden the skills base of Australian industry and
allow industry to become internationally competitive, to permit
employees to engage in a wider range of tasks and enhance their
ability to access higher pay through career paths and training.
The competency-based system continues to operate
in those industries where it has been employed. Manufacturing
generally has moved over to the new structure and the (former)
Metal Industry Award was adopted by the AIRC as the benchmark award
for setting classifications and pay rates in its August 1989
National Wage Case Decision.(12) A clear manifestation of the joint
efforts of governments to improve the skills based training system,
is the adoption by all governments of the national Australian
Standards Framework (ASF) for detailing skill levels used in
apprenticeships and traineeships.
However, this principle was applied on an award
by award basis and the move to competency based training and career
paths has not been uniform. For example, there has been slower
movement by the sections of the Services sector to restructure
award classifications on to the competency-based system. It has
been observed particularly in the Carmichael Report(13) on
Australian skills and training, that sections of the Services
sector have relied on a more disparate model of skill development
than that pertaining to trade training in manufacturing. The
Carmichael Report was a vocal supporter of
competency-based training.(14) In its review of the progress of
sectors adopting competency-based training, the Carmichael
Report noted that some areas of the Services sector such as
the retail industry were lagging other sectors:
The retail industry favours an evolutionary
approach to the development of competency standards. It proposes
that any development of standards should take place at enterprise
or local level, which may then lead to industry standards. This was
based on a claim of virtual enterprise uniqueness in training
needs.(15)
A major initiative to assist the services sector
to adopt competency-based training, including training for juniors,
was the creation of the federal National Training Wage Award
1994. It has been used as a training and pay regime for
thousands of diverse industries and occupations (stipulated in the
schedules attached to the award). It embodies many of the themes of
the Carmichael Report. Specifically, it links classifications and
pay scales to school achievement and competency required of the
job, not the age of the people employed under the award although
there are obvious links between the ages of school leavers (ie,
Year 10 or Year 12) and levels of competency expressed in that
award. It also represents an 'add-on' to traditional award based
training systems (for apprentices and trainees). It was designed to
fill the gap for industries that had not formalised award training
schemes.
How young people are paid
Young people are paid as:
-
- apprentices
-
- trainees
-
- juniors, or
-
- adults.
A 'junior' differs from apprentices and trainees
in that s/he is expected to be working full-time receiving no
training. Their pay is usually based on their age starting at 45%
of an adult's pay for a 16 year old and increasing in steps on each
birthday until age 21 is reached when juniors are entitled to adult
pay.(16)
The Joint Governments' Submission notes that
some 56 per cent of those employed aged 21 years or younger are
employed under junior rates, ie, using 1996 ABS data, the Joint
Governments' Submission estimates that some 375 000 out of 724 000
employees aged below 21 years were paid under junior rates, ie
under State and federal awards and agreements.(17) About 30 per
cent are paid as adults and 13 per cent paid as
apprentices/trainees.
It is these 'junior rates' which may be affected
by legislated restrictions on age discrimination, since apprentices
and trainees are not classified by age; they are classified on a
'time served' basis which is not the same as age. The award
classifications reviewed under the SEP pertained to adults, and
junior rates of pay have not been subject to structural efficiency
principle considerations, as noted in the Joint Governments'
Submission:
A related development ... to the recent history
of junior rates, was the agreement to principles and guidelines for
reforming youth and training wages by all Commonwealth, State, and
Territory Ministers for Labour in 1990. These principles/guidelines
reflected governments' concerns about the consequences for youth
employment of the changes arising from award restructuring. They
included a principle that 'There should be no hasty movement away
from youth/age related wage rates in those areas where they now
apply, unless a suitable skills and experience based replacement is
available and suitable provision can be made for unskilled young
workers.' All governments restated their commitment to these
principles in May 1995.(18)
An important step in moving to competency based
classifications pertaining to employees who might have been
classified as juniors was taken in the AIRC's decision in the
Furnishing Trades Award 1981.(19) As is explained in
chapter 2 of the Joint Governments' Submission, this decision
attempted to correlate junior pay with 'exit rates' as training
modules for the relevant industry were completed by young people.
This appeared to introduce a form of competency-based training for
'juniors' and provided a pay scale to fill the gap between the
wages afforded to trainees (after training was completed) and wages
applying to more fully competent workers.
Age Discrimination
Age discrimination provisions to limit
employment discrimination under federal industrial legislation were
moved during debate on the Industrial Relations Reform Bill 1993.
Certain parts of the Bill dealing with awards and agreements were
amended (at the instigation of the Australian Democrats and the WA
Greens) to include further provisions that awards and agreements be
non-discriminatory, and age was itemised as one of the
non-discriminatory criteria. These provisions reflected principles
of ILO (Discrimination (Employment and Occupation) Convention
(No.111) which deals with discrimination in the workplace.
It was later discovered that the new provisions
might undermine awards and agreements that set specific pay rates
for juniors. The Industrial Relations Act 1988 was further
amended in 1994 to neutralise this possibility.(20) The then
government proposed to defer the application of age discrimination
by way of an amendment. A breathing space to mid 1997 was provided
legislatively and junior rates of pay continued in operation.
Age discrimination under the Workplace Relations
Act
With the change of government in 1996, a new
Act, the Workplace Relations Act was passed containing similar
anti-discrimination provisions to those in the Industrial
Relations Act 1988, and thus arguably faces a similar conflict
in respect of the discrimination provisions and junior rates. After
consultations between the Government and the Australian Democrats
an Agreement between the Commonwealth Government and the
Australian Democrats on the Workplace Relations Bill (October
1996) was devised to pass the Bill. It devised a similar stopgap
measure: defer the application of the discrimination provision
until mid 2000. This allowed junior rates to continue in effect
whilst the AIRC was to conduct a review of junior rates and put
possible solutions. The AIRC was to report to Parliament not later
than one year before the expiry of the exemption.
There are two important provisions.
The first provision is to be found in the
legislation that introduced the Workplace Relations Act
1996 (by amending the Industrial Relations Act 1988).
That legislation is the Workplace Relations and Other
Legislation Amendment Act 1996. This Act introduces
transitionary provisions to move from the IR Act to the
Workplace Relations Act. Subitem 54 (1) of these transitionary
provisions states:
A provision of an award does not discriminate
against an employee for the purposes of par 49 (8) or 51 (7)(f)
merely because:
it provides for a junior rate of pay ...
And, under the Workplace Relations Act sections
143(1D) and (1E), (and via subitem 54(2) of the WROLA transitional
provisions, award junior rate clauses will not be held
discriminatory until 22 June 2000.(21)
Section 120B of the Workplace Relations Act set
out in detail that the AIRC is to conduct an inquiry into junior
rates, and report to Parliament:
SECTION 120B-COMMISSION TO REPORT ON JUNIOR RATES OF
PAY
The relevant provisions are as follows:
120B(1) [Feasibility report]...Before 22 June
1999, a Full Bench must prepare a report for the Minister on the
feasibility of replacing junior rates with non-discriminatory
alternatives.
120B(2) [Contents]...The report must include
assessments of:
(a) whether it is desirable to replace junior
rates with non-discriminatory alternatives; and
(b) the consequences for youth employment of
abolishing junior rates; and
(c) the utility of junior rates:
(i) for different types of employment; and
(ii) for different industries; and
(iii) in the school-to-work transition.
120B(3) [Report to be tabled in
Parliament]...The Minister must cause a copy of the report to be
tabled in each House of the Parliament as soon as practicable after
the Minister receives it.
120B(4) [``junior rates defined]...In this
section, junior rates means junior rates of pay.
On 25 August 1998, a Full Bench of the AIRC
comprising Justice Munro, Deputy President Duncan and Commissioner
Raffaelli issued a Statement and Outline of Procedure for its
Junior Rates Inquiry. The Inquiry is to focus on:
-
- whether it is desirable to replace junior rates with
alternatives that do not discriminate on the basis of age;
-
- the consequences for youth employment of abolishing junior
rates; and
-
- the utility of junior rates for different types of employment,
for different industries and in the school-to-work transition.
The AIRC also signalled its intention to produce
an issues paper by November 1998 and in February 1999 publish a
paper setting out its provisional findings. It is due to complete
its report to Parliament by 30 April 1999.
ACCI Submission (Summary)
The case to retain aged-based pay rates for
juniors has rested predominantly on the needs of the retail and
fast food industries. Some sectors of these industries have not
adopted competency based award classifications for juniors
therefore there is the perception that an 18 year old will be able
to perform a task with equal application as a 20 year old.
Accordingly, labour costs could rise under competency-based pay.
And, if an employee moves through competency levels, but is
required to perform work of a lower competency level, what rate
should be paid?
The ACCI has made the following points in its
submission to the AIRC inquiry favouring the retention of junior
rates. They are:
-
- Youth unemployment is already high, and the onus on those
supporting the removal of junior rates is to show that such a
change would not damage the job prospects of unemployed young
people.
-
- Costs Matter: The higher the cost of employing, the fewer
persons will be employed.
-
- Young people have fewer skills and less experience
-
- Young people are less mature than are adult employees
-
- Employers believe that young people have fewer skills and are
less mature than adult workers.
-
- It is not discrimination to pay less to young workers who are
less skilled and who have less experience
-
- The prime interest for young people is to gain workplace
experience and develop labour market skills
-
- Where junior rates have been eliminated there has been a
reduction in youth employment
-
- International data show that paying adult wages to young people
costs them jobs
-
- Removing junior rates will lead to higher retail
prices.(22)
ACTU submission (summary)
-
- The ACTU submission sets out the roles that the AIRC must
perform under the legislation. It notes that Full Benches of the
AIRC can determine principles dealing with awards.
-
- In carrying out its functions the AIRC may need to deal with
the merits of an award concerning junior rates on a case by case
basis. However, the ACTU observes that 'it is utterly inappropriate
for a Full Bench of this Commission to be asked to provide advice
to the Minister and the Parliament on the merits or otherwise of
any contemplated changes to the Act'.
-
- The ACTU stresses that replacement of junior rates with (any
number) of non-discriminatory alternatives is feasible.
-
- The AIRC should not make an assessment of the desirability of
replacing junior rates with non-discriminatory alternatives as
making such an assessment may pre-empt a determination of the
merits of a later application (which may seek the replacement of
junior rates).
-
- In relation to the terms of reference relating to the probable
consequence for youth unemployment of abolishing junior rates, the
ACTU submits that there needs to be a clear distinction between the
likely consequences of abolition simpliciter and the
effective abolition through replacement with specified
non-discriminatory alternatives.
-
- As to the utility of junior rates for different types of
employment, in different industries and in the school-to-work
transition, the ACTU suggests that the key issue is 'useful to
whom' and it is not to be assumed that the utility of junior rates
to young workers and their families is necessarily commensurate
with the utility of the same provisions to actual or potential
employers.(23)
Joint Governments' Submission (summary)
-
- Junior rates are inherently conducive to youth employment and
any inequity occasioned by junior rates is greatly outweighed by
the inequities consequent on their abolition.
-
- There are no feasible alternatives to junior rates -
non-discriminatory or otherwise - as all of the available
alternatives have a detrimental effect on youth employment, do not
properly reflect differences in skills and maturity between young
people and adults, or are difficult and costly to implement and
administer.
-
- The anti-discrimination provisions of the Workplace Relations
Act are concerned with equality of opportunity just as much as with
equality of treatment. This submission argues that in assessing the
status of junior wage provisions it is essential to consider the
practical effect if those provisions are removed, as well as
considering the practical effect of the junior wage provisions
currently in place.
-
- Removing those provisions would severely damage the youth
labour market in Australia, and would be likely to result in many
young people experiencing protracted unemployment, with potentially
permanently damaged prospects of labour force integration and
reduced career prospects over the longer term.
-
- Therefore to the extent that junior wage provisions are
considered to be discriminatory, they should be characterised as a
special measure that operates beneficially to meet the particular
needs of young people, who are generally recognised as needing
special assistance.
-
- In the Joint Governments' view, the continuation of junior
rates should be supported on this basis, that is, that they are a
positive assistance to youth employment and removing them would be
detrimental to youth employment. This is the principal reason that
the Commonwealth proposes to legislate for the retention of junior
rates.
-
- In this respect the Commonwealth's proposed legislation would
align with the laws that currently operate in the States and
Territories, under which junior rates are exempted from anti-age
discrimination provisions.
-
- This, together with proposed provisions designed to make junior
rates more widely available, and to ensure that regard is had to
the promotion of youth employment and the reduction of youth
unemployment in the making and varying of awards, will ensure that
young people are neither disadvantaged nor their labour market
position compromised.
The effect of this Bill on the Junior Rates
Inquiry
State jurisdictions have faced and addressed the
matter of junior wages and discrimination with much less fanfare
than is the situation federally. The Joint Governments' Submission
notes:
All State and Territory Governments, with the
exception of Tasmania, have introduced age discrimination
legislation. Each provides an exemption for junior rates from the
requirements of the legislation. The exemption is permanent in all
States except New South Wales where it can be repealed by
proclamation (24)
The present Bill contains a similar solution to
the junior rates/pay discrimination problem to that adopted by the
States [see proposed subsection 88B(4)]:
For the purposes of paragraph 3(e) junior wage
provisions are not to be treated as constituting discrimination by
reason of age.
This is the key provision of the new Bill.
Critics of this approach will suggest that it is
difficult to avoid the conclusion that the introduction of the Bill
is pre-empting the AIRC's inquiry to evaluate the possibility of
non-discriminatory alternatives under s.120B. However, it should be
noted that the Bill is not so prescriptive as to prevent the wider
application of non-discriminatory classification structures,
including to those now employed as juniors.
Possible Employment Effects
As to whether there is an employment
consequence, the one possible consequence being raised is if 18/19
year olds will finish up being paid as adults if junior rate are
abolished - in this case the employers are saying that they will
hire adults instead. There is copious literature on the effect of
minimum wage increases (some is attached to the Joint Governments
and Productivity Commission reports). However, some of it does not
address the 'displacement issue' as it relates squarely to the US
minimum wage debate, and not the Australian institutional settings
or the Australian labour market.
In the US, some key studies have found that
increases in the minimum wage have not harmed employment. The US
does not have legislated junior pay rates, and 16 year olds have to
be paid what in Australia would be called the minimum adult wage
($US 5.15) an hour after 90 days.
A particularly important document in respect of
junior rates and youth employment is the Productivity Commission
Report, Youth Wages and Employment (the PC
Report).(25)
As is noted at the start of the PC report, the
study arose from consultations on its research program, which led
to specific requests for work on this topic by several government
departments and other organisations. The paper was prepared
accordingly as a technical exercise to help inform the forthcoming
review of junior rates of pay. The PC report provides some useful
data. In summary it says:
-
- At face value, the minimum wage studies (primarily undertaken
in the United States) suggest that the effect on employment of
changes in the minimum wage is small.
-
- However, it is important to remember that even among teenagers,
who are often the most affected by minimum wages, the proportion
being paid the minimum wage is relatively small. Minimum wage
studies do not say anything about what would happen if the wages of
the remaining teenagers were changed relative to employees in other
demographic groups.
-
- Studies of this question look at substitution between
particular types of labour. The estimated responsiveness of youth
employment to youth wages in these studies is considerably higher
than the estimates from the minimum wage studies. The weight of
evidence suggests a relatively large (much more than proportionate)
decline in youth employment in response to an increase in the youth
wage.
-
- Teenage real wage costs (as measured by real hourly earnings)
have increased slightly. This could explain, at least in part, the
decline in full-time employment. But for teenage part-time workers,
both real hourly earnings and total hours worked have risen.
-
- Increased demand for part-time workers resulting from extended
trading hours in retail and other service industries could be one
factor explaining this trend. While the teenage wage has not
changed much relative to the adult wage, teenage employment has
declined relative to adult employment.
-
- For teenage full-time workers, wage costs and employment have
both fallen relative to adults. For teenage part-time workers, wage
costs and employment have both increased relative to adults.
Neither trend is consistent with a strong degree of substitution
between teenage and adult workers. Indeed, the trends suggest the
opposite.
-
- The purpose of the study was to examine the determinants of
youth employment in order to shed light on the possible
implications of abolishing junior rates of pay in State and Federal
awards. To the extent that replacing such awards with
non-discriminatory alternatives would lead to an increase in youth
wages, the results suggest quite strongly that there would be a
more than proportionate reduction in youth employment
The Productivity Commission's most significant
finding in terms of the present Bill however, is that:
The analysis also finds a significant negative
relationship between youth employment and youth wages. The best
estimates suggest that a 1 per cent increase in youth wages would
lead to a decrease in youth employment of between 2 and 5 per cent
in industries employing a relatively high proportion of young
persons.(26)
This finding, clearly gives strong support to
the wages effect argument referred to above.
What (if anything) is different about
the labour market?
The Productivity Commission adopts a
neoclassical economic approach to analysing the employment of young
people and the possible impact of changes to their wages. This
rests predominantly on a theory of the relationship between demand
and supply of labour where an increase in the price (wages) results
in a fall in the demand (employment).
This is the dominant view of how all markets
clear under competitive conditions.
This view is now so pervasive that it is worth
noting that it is not as readily accepted in relation to the
behaviour of labour markets.(27)
John Quiggin is one of a number of academic
commentators who argue that features of the labour market make it
less amenable to the application of standard neoclassical
theory.(28)
The points he and others make are that even in
simple commodity markets there are problems with the application of
the neoclassical model due to information problems, and these
problems are more complex for the labour market. This is not meant
to say that standard neoclassical analysis is not appropriate for
the labour market, rather that these analyses need to be
complimented by more complex theories about its operation.
Quiggin's argument is similar to that described by a predecessor to
the Productivity Commission, the Economic Planning and Advisory
Commission (EPAC) and a substantial number of labour market
economists. For example, in Future Labour Market Issues for
Australia,(29) EPAC argued:
-
- Labour is an input to production and the income from labour is
also a source of demand for goods and services. Labour thus
performs a dual role in the economy and for this reason governments
have adopted income policies as a form of intervention so as to
factor in macro economic effects.
-
- Labour is distinctive because of factors such as motivation,
effort and skills. Indeed Dr David Peetz has recently reported on
the importance of the incentive effects of minimum wages to
labour.(30)
-
- The market for labour is not homogeneous. It can be
characterised by many forms of natural and acquired ability. It is
not static. Individuals also differ in their preferences for
leisure/work and between different types of work. Labour is also
divided regionally because of the cost of moving house. There are
thousands of sub-markets for labour with varying degrees of
mobility between them.
-
- There is considerable uncertainty in the employment contract.
Employees often have incomplete information about the enterprise's
prospects for continued operation. Employers have incomplete
knowledge about a prospective employee's commitment to stay in the
job. There are also substantial costs for both sides in hiring and
firing.
-
- There is also the question of bargaining power. Individuals do
not have the resources or knowledge about prospective wages and
conditions at an enterprise as does the employer. Employees often
join unions to minimise some of these mobility costs and increase
their bargaining power.
-
- Employment decisions may also include decisions about housing
and training that involve longer-term costs. They may accumulate
experience in one workplace but this may also involve a loss of
flexibility to move to another occupation. These factors act to
reduce the bargaining power of employees.
Other authors, some quite conservative by
disposition, hold similar (though obviously not identical) views
about the unique nature of labour markets to those expressed by
Quiggin, Peetz and others.(31)
Junior pay: international
arrangements
The following outline of international
arrangements for setting youth rates is extracted from the Joint
Governments' Submission (Chapter 2):
The OECD Employment Outlook for June
1998 indicates that 17 OECD countries apart from Australia
currently have a statutory or national minimum wage which cuts
across almost all sectors of the economy. In addition, the UK has
also announced its intention to introduce a national minimum wage
in April 1999. Sub-minimum rates for young workers are available in
over half these OECD countries
The arrangements for discounting minimum wages
vary from country to country. In the Netherlands, Belgium and
Luxembourg, the adult rate is reduced successively for each year
below 23, 21 and 18 years of age respectively. By comparison,
French junior wage rates are only enforced for employees aged 17 or
below with less than 6 months experience.
The setting of minimum wages for young workers
has also changed over recent years in several countries. In 1998,
Spain adopted a single statutory minimum wage with no distinction
by age. In 1994, New Zealand introduced a minimum rate for workers
aged less than 20 at 60 per cent of the adult minimum wage.
In the US, a youth rate was introduced at the
Federal level in 1996, but it only applies for the first 90
consecutive calendar days of employment.
[A more useful explanation of the detail of the
US minimum wage is given below in Chapter 3 of the Productivity
Commission's Report, Youth Wages and Employment]:
Much of the literature on the effects of minimum
wages on employment comes from the United States. Federal minimum
wages are set in nominal terms by the US Congress at irregular
intervals. So, for example, between January 1981 and April 1990,
there was no increase in the minimum rate. The current Federal
minimum wage is $US5.15 per hour and this applies to 90 per cent of
non-supervisory and non-farm employees. As of August 1996, there is
also a sub-minimum wage for employees under 20 years of age of
$US4.25, although in practice this is not often used (Katz 1998).
For employees who earn tips, the employers are only required to pay
$US2.13 per hour, on the assumption that the addition of tips will
bring the total payment up to the Federal minimum rate of $US5.15.
Minimum wages are also set at the State level in the United States
and in some States, these minimums are above the Federal levels. In
these cases, the State minimum applies.
Returning to Chapter 2 of the Joint Governments'
Submission:
The UK Government recently decided to accept the
recommendations of the UK Low Pay Commission to exclude 16 and 17
year olds from the proposed national hourly minimum wage. The UK
Government also decided to introduce a youth development rate for
18-20 year olds, because of its concerns about the impact of the
minimum wage on youth employment.
The Irish National Minimum Wage Commission has
also recently recommended a separate minimum wage for under 18 year
olds set at 70 per cent of the full time adult rate, and a training
rate of 75, 80 and 90 per cent of the adult rate for job entrants
without experience in their first three years of employment,
regardless of age.
The Explanatory Memorandum provides a detailed,
accurate and useful synopsis of the proposed changes and there is
no need, given the foregoing discussion, to repeat all that
material here.
Schedule 1 makes amendments to the Workplace
Relations Act 1996.
Items 1-4 make various
amendments required to direct the AIRC's attention to the
importance of protecting the competitive position of young persons
in the labour market when exercising its functions.
As noted, above, these provisions only direct
that the AIRC take certain considerations into account. They do not
and cannot direct the Commission what the outcome should be in any
particular matter. The amendments must also stop short of directing
the Commission as to how much weight it should give to the special
circumstances of young people. There is also no attempt to direct
the AIRC as to how it should balance this proposed requirement with
other public interest provisions already in the Act (see above).
Lastly, it is left to the Commission to decide what particular
policies will protect the interests of young workers.
Item 5 amends paragraph
143(1C)(e) to require the Commission to ensure that in making any
award, it must give consideration to inserting junior wage rates.
It is this provision that appears to offer the prospect that there
will be an increase in the proportion of young employees covered by
junior rates. Whether there is such a spread of junior rates is,
however, ultimately a matter for the AIRC.
Item 6 and 7 provide for the
permanent exemption of junior rates in awards and certified
agreements from the anti-discrimination provisions of the Workplace
Relations Act. As noted above, there is presently statutory
exemption to the relevant anti-discrimination provisions, but it is
due to expire on 22 June 2000.(32)
The Government appears keen to make the present
temporary exemption permanent as a matter of urgency. As noted
above, the AIRC is currently conducting a thorough inquiry into the
feasibility of replacing junior rates with non-discriminatory
alternatives, pursuant to section 120B of the Workplace Relations
Act. That Inquiry is due to report to Minister Reith no later than
22 June 1999, ie 12 months before the present exemption expires or
requires further extension.
Schedule 2 deals with proposed amendments to the
Workplace Relations and Other Legislation Amendment Act
1996.
These changes relate to the award simplification
process and have a similar intent and operative effect to those
amendments being proposed in relation to the Workplace Relations
Act.
-
- ABS, Labour Force (Preliminary), Catalogue No.6202, 12
November 1998, p 10.
- The so called 'Five Economist's Plan' is a recent example of a
policy prescription that seeks to incorporate a range of
theoretical approaches to the development of policy. Professor
Peter Dawkins, Professor John Freebairn, Professor Ross Garnaut, Dr
Michael Keating and Mr Chris Richardson, 'Dear John: how to create
more jobs', The Australian, 26 October 1998, p 13. Also
Ross Gittins, 'In the five economist's plan, the compromise is
golden', The Age, 7 November 1998, B3 for a discussion of
the theoretical cross currents.
- Sydney Morning Herald, 27 November 1998, p 1.
- Ross Gittins, 'Why jobs myth persists', Sydney Morning
Herald, 4 February 1998, p. 17.
- Ibid.
- Refer to the Appendices for long-term trends in youth
unemployment.
- ABS, Labour Force Statistics on Microfiche, November
1998.
- R v Commonwealth Conciliation and Arbitration Commission;
Ex parte Amalgamated Engineering Union (1968) 118 CLR 219.
- www.dwrsb.gov.au.index1.htm
- page 101.
- Principle 3: Previous National Wage Case Increases in
Safety Net Review (Wages), AIRC, April 1998, Print Q1998,
p. 64.
- AIRC, Print H9100.
- The Australian Vocational Certificate Training System,
Report of the Employment and Skills Formation Council to the
National Board of Employment Education and Training, 1992.
- Ibid., p. 61.
- Ibid., p. 63.
- See Chapter 2 of the Joint Governments' Submission to the
Junior Rates Inquiry http://www.dwrsb.gov.au.index1.htm.
- Ibid., p 10.
- Ibid., p 7.
- Print N4645, September 1996, p.7.
- Refer: Marco Bini, DPL, Bills Digest 89/1994,
Industrial Relations Amendment Bill No. 2 1994.
- Except where the AIRC decides on a case by case basis that the
paragraph should apply.
- 'Youth Employment and Junior Rates', ACCI Review,
October 1998.
- ACTU Submission to Junior Rates Inquiry, C. No. 33985 of 1998.
ACTU, written submission, November 1998.
- op cit., p 10.
- 98, (http://pc.gov.au/research/other /youthemp/index.html).
- oductivity Commission, Youth Wages and Employment, pp
xi - xiii.
- Lester C Thurow, Dangerous Currents: The State of
Economics, 1983, pp. 173-215.
- Why Isn't the Market for Labour like the Market for
Oranges, mimeo, Centre for Economic Policy Research, ANU,
1995.
- Commission Paper No.12, 1996.
- 'Minimum wages and jobs', The Australian Financial
Review, 5 February 1998.
- See P. P. McGuinness, 'Labour, Discrimination, Employment',
Student Economic Briefs 1985, Australian Financial Review,
1985, pp 84-92. Refer also: Report of the Committee of Review,
Australian Industrial Relations Law and Systems (Hancock
Report), Volume 2, April 1985; and Keith Whitfield, The
Australian Labour Market, 1987, esp pp. 36-61.
- Although the AIRC may, noted above, extend it on a case by case
basis.
RATIO OF F/T UNEMPLOYMENT RATE FOR 15-19 YEAR OLDS TO
UNEMPLOYMENT RATE FOR ALL PERSONS, SEASONALLY ADJUSTED
SERIES
|
Unemployment Rate (%), s.a.
|
|
Ratio full-time une rate
|
|
Aged 15-19 looking for full-time work
|
Total persons
|
|
for youth to une rate total persons
|
Aug-79
|
19.5
|
6.1
|
|
3.2
|
Aug-80
|
18.8
|
6.2
|
|
3.0
|
Aug-81
|
16.1
|
5.8
|
|
2.8
|
Aug-82
|
19.1
|
7.0
|
|
2.7
|
Aug-83
|
26.9
|
10.2
|
|
2.6
|
Aug-84
|
25.0
|
8.8
|
|
2.8
|
Aug-85
|
21.6
|
8.2
|
|
2.6
|
Aug-86
|
21.7
|
8.3
|
|
2.6
|
Aug-87
|
22.3
|
8.1
|
|
2.8
|
Aug-88
|
17.8
|
7.1
|
|
2.5
|
Aug-89
|
14.9
|
6.0
|
|
2.5
|
Aug-90
|
19.6
|
7.2
|
|
2.7
|
Aug-91
|
28.4
|
9.8
|
|
2.9
|
Aug-92
|
33.9
|
10.9
|
|
3.1
|
Aug-93
|
32.6
|
11.1
|
|
2.9
|
Aug-94
|
28.3
|
9.5
|
|
3.0
|
Aug-95
|
28.4
|
8.3
|
|
3.4
|
Aug-96
|
28.0
|
8.7
|
|
3.2
|
Aug-97
|
27.6
|
8.7
|
|
3.2
|
Aug-98
|
28.2
|
8.1
|
|
3.5
|

Source: ABS, The Labour Force (Cat. No. 6202.0)
RATIO OF UNEMPLOYMENT RATE FOR 15-19 YEAR OLDS TO
UNEMPLOYMENT RATE FOR ALL PERSONS, ORIGINAL SERIES
|
Unemployment Rate (%), original
|
|
Ratio of une rate for youth
|
|
Aged 15-19
|
Total persons
|
|
to une rate total persons
|
Aug-66
|
3.2
|
1.6
|
|
2.0
|
Aug-67
|
3.3
|
1.7
|
|
1.9
|
Aug-68
|
3.4
|
1.6
|
|
2.1
|
Aug-69
|
2.9
|
1.5
|
|
1.9
|
Aug-70
|
3.2
|
1.4
|
|
2.3
|
Aug-71
|
3.7
|
1.7
|
|
2.2
|
Aug-72
|
5.8
|
2.5
|
|
2.3
|
Aug-73
|
4.7
|
1.8
|
|
2.6
|
Aug-74
|
5.8
|
2.4
|
|
2.4
|
Aug-75
|
12.9
|
4.6
|
|
2.8
|
Aug-76
|
14.2
|
4.7
|
|
3.0
|
Aug-77
|
18.0
|
5.7
|
|
3.2
|
Aug-78
|
16.8
|
6.2
|
|
2.7
|
Aug-79
|
17.3
|
5.8
|
|
3.0
|
Aug-80
|
16.6
|
5.9
|
|
2.8
|
Aug-81
|
13.9
|
5.6
|
|
2.5
|
Aug-82
|
16.6
|
6.7
|
|
2.5
|
Aug-83
|
22.6
|
9.9
|
|
2.3
|
Aug-84
|
20.9
|
8.5
|
|
2.5
|
Aug-85
|
18.2
|
7.9
|
|
2.3
|
Aug-86
|
19.1
|
8.0
|
|
2.4
|
Aug-87
|
18.7
|
7.8
|
|
2.4
|
Aug-88
|
15.5
|
6.8
|
|
2.3
|
Aug-89
|
13.7
|
5.7
|
|
2.4
|
Aug-90
|
16.5
|
7.0
|
|
2.4
|
Aug-91
|
21.0
|
9.5
|
|
2.2
|
Aug-92
|
25.0
|
10.5
|
|
2.4
|
Aug-93
|
23.0
|
10.7
|
|
2.1
|
Aug-94
|
20.3
|
9.2
|
|
2.2
|
Aug-95
|
20.0
|
8.1
|
|
2.5
|
Aug-96
|
19.5
|
8.5
|
|
2.3
|
Aug-97
|
19.3
|
8.4
|
|
2.3
|
Aug-98
|
18.8
|
7.9
|
|
2.4
|

Source: ABS, The Labour Force (Cat. No. 6202.0)
15-19 YEAR OLD MALES - REAL EARNINGS AND THEIR FULL-TIME
UNEMPLOYMENT RATE
|
Male 15-19 Year Olds
|
|
Real Earnings*
|
Full-time Une Rate
|
|
$
|
%
|
Aug-88
|
309
|
16.6
|
Aug-89
|
311
|
12.9
|
Aug-90
|
314
|
18.0
|
Aug-91
|
310
|
27.0
|
Aug-92
|
315
|
31.3
|
Aug-93
|
309
|
30.1
|
Aug-94
|
326
|
23.6
|
Aug-95
|
305
|
24.3
|
Aug-96
|
na
|
25.4
|
Aug-97
|
330
|
25.1
|
* Weekly earnings of full-time employed 15-19 year old males at
constant (Aug 1997) prices
|

Source: Based on data published in ABS, Weekly Earnings of
Employees (Distribution) (Cat. No. 6310.0) and ABS, The Labour
Force (Cat. No. 6202.0)
15-19 YEAR OLD FEMALES - REAL EARNINGS AND THEIR
FULL-TIME UNEMPLOYMENT RATE
|
Female 15-19 Year Olds
|
|
Real Earnings*
|
F/T Une Rate
|
|
$
|
%
|
Aug-88
|
288
|
17.6
|
Aug-89
|
294
|
16.3
|
Aug-90
|
289
|
20.6
|
Aug-91
|
298
|
29.1
|
Aug-92
|
301
|
36.6
|
Aug-93
|
302
|
35.2
|
Aug-94
|
306
|
33.6
|
Aug-95
|
295
|
33.1
|
Aug-96
|
na
|
30.4
|
Aug-97
|
329
|
29.7
|
* Weekly earnings of full-time employed 15-19 year old females
at constant (Aug 1997) prices
|

Source: Based on data published in ABS, Weekly Earnings of
Employees (Distribution) (Cat. No. 6310.0) and ABS, The Labour
Force (Cat. No. 6202.0)
Steve O'Neil, Tony Kryger, Bob Bennett
2 December 1998
Bills Digest Service
Information and Research Services
This paper has been prepared for general distribution to
Senators and Members of the Australian Parliament. While great care
is taken to ensure that the paper is accurate and balanced, the
paper is written using information publicly available at the time
of production. The views expressed are those of the author and
should not be attributed to the Information and Research Services
(IRS). Advice on legislation or legal policy issues contained in
this paper is provided for use in parliamentary debate and for
related parliamentary purposes. This paper is not professional
legal opinion. Readers are reminded that the paper is not an
official parliamentary or Australian government document.
IRS staff are available to discuss the paper's contents with
Senators and Members
and their staff but not with members of the public.
ISSN 1328-8091
Commonwealth of Australia 1998
Except to the extent of the uses permitted under the
Copyright Act 1968, no part of this publication may be
reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, including
information storage and retrieval systems, without the prior
written consent of the Parliamentary Library, other than by Members
of the Australian Parliament in the course of their official
duties.
Published by the Department of the Parliamentary Library,
1998.
Back to top